]> pere.pagekite.me Git - text-destroy-surveillance.git/blob - public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.html
Updated PO files from POT.
[text-destroy-surveillance.git] / public / how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.html
1 <html><head><meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=UTF-8"><title>Comment détruire le capitalisme de la surveillance</title><meta name="generator" content="DocBook XSL Stylesheets V1.79.1"><meta name="description" content="Our devices and services gather most of the data that the NSA mines for its surveillance project. We pay for these devices and the services they connect to, and then we painstakingly perform the data-entry tasks associated with logging facts about our lives, opinions, and preferences. Thanks to Big Tech, Surveillance capitalism is everywhere. This is not because it is really good at manipulating our behaviour, or the rogue abuse of corporate power. It is the result of unchecked monopolism and the abusive behavior it abets. It is the system working as intended and expected. Cory Doctorow has written an extended critique of Shoshana Zuboff's The Age of Surveillance Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at the New Frontier of Power, with a non-magical analysis of the problem leading to a different proposal for a solution."><style type="text/css">
2 body { background-image: url('images/draft.png');
3 background-repeat: no-repeat;
4 background-position: top left;
5 /* The following properties make the watermark "fixed" on the page. */
6 /* I think that's just a bit too distracting for the reader... */
7 /* background-attachment: fixed; */
8 /* background-position: center center; */
9 }</style></head><body bgcolor="white" text="black" link="#0000FF" vlink="#840084" alink="#0000FF"><div lang="fr" class="article"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title"><a name="index"></a>Comment détruire le capitalisme de la surveillance</h2></div><div><div class="authorgroup"><div class="author"><h3 class="author"><span class="firstname">Cory</span> <span class="surname">Doctorow</span></h3></div></div></div><div><p class="copyright">Copyright © 2020 Cory Doctorow</p></div><div><p class="copyright">Copyright © 2020 Petter Reinholdtsen</p></div><div><div class="legalnotice"><a name="idm18"></a><p>
10 Comment détruire le capitalisme de la surveillance par Cory Doctorow.
11 </p><p>
12 Publié par Petter Reinholdtsen.
13 </p><p>
14 ISBN 978-82-93828-XX-X (édition reliée)
15 </p><p>
16 ISBN 978-82-93828-XX-X (livre de poche)
17 </p><p>
18 ISBN 978-82-93828-XX-X (ePub)
19 </p><p>
20 Ce livre est disponible à la vente sur <a class="ulink" href="https://www.lulu.com/" target="_top">https://www.lulu.com/</a>.
21 </p><p>
22 Si vous trouvez des fautes de frappe, des erreurs ou si vous avez d'autres
23 corrections sur le texte traduit, veuillez mettre à jour <a class="ulink" href="https://hosted.weblate.org/projects/rms-personal-data-safe/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism/fr/" target="_top">https://hosted.weblate.org/projects/rms-personal-data-safe/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism/fr/</a>.
24 </p><p>
25 <span class="inlinemediaobject"><img src="images/cc-some-rights-reserved.png" align="middle" height="38" alt="Creative Commons, certains droits réservés"></span>
26 </p><p>
27 Ce livre est sous licence Creative Commons. Cette licence permet toute
28 utilisation de ce travail, tant que l'attribution est donnée et qu'aucun
29 matériel dérivé n'est distribué. Pour plus d'informations sur la licence,
30 visitez <a class="ulink" href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nd/4.0/" target="_top">https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nd/4.0/</a>.
31 </p></div></div><div><div class="abstract"><p class="title"><b>Résumé</b></p><p>
32 Our devices and services gather most of the data that the NSA mines for its
33 surveillance project. We pay for these devices and the services they connect
34 to, and then we painstakingly perform the data-entry tasks associated with
35 logging facts about our lives, opinions, and preferences.
36 </p><p>
37 Thanks to Big Tech, Surveillance capitalism is everywhere. This is not
38 because it is really good at manipulating our behaviour, or the rogue abuse
39 of corporate power. It is the result of unchecked monopolism and the
40 abusive behavior it abets. It is the system working as intended and
41 expected. Cory Doctorow has written an extended critique of Shoshana
42 Zuboff's The Age of Surveillance Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at
43 the New Frontier of Power, with a non-magical analysis of the problem
44 leading to a different proposal for a solution.
45 </p></div></div></div><hr></div><div class="toc"><p><b>Table des matières</b></p><dl class="toc"><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#the-net-of-a-thousand-lies">The net of a thousand lies</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#digital-rights-activism-a-quarter-century-on">Digital rights activism, a quarter-century on</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#tech-exceptionalism-then-and-now">Tech exceptionalism, then and now</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#dont-believe-the-hype">Don’t believe the hype</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#what-is-persuasion">What is persuasion?</a></span></dt><dd><dl><dt><span class="sect2"><a href="#segmenting">1. Segmenting</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect2"><a href="#deception">2. Deception</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect2"><a href="#domination">3. Domination</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect2"><a href="#bypassing-our-rational-faculties">4. Bypassing our rational faculties</a></span></dt></dl></dd><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#if-data-is-the-new-oil-then-surveillance-capitalisms-engine-has-a-leak">If data is the new oil, then surveillance capitalism’s engine has a leak</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#what-is-facebook">What is Facebook?</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#monopoly-and-the-right-to-the-future-tense">Monopoly and the right to the future tense</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#search-order-and-the-right-to-the-future-tense">Search order and the right to the future tense</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#monopolists-can-afford-sleeping-pills-for-watchdogs">Monopolists can afford sleeping pills for watchdogs</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#privacy-and-monopoly">Privacy and monopoly</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#ronald-reagan-pioneer-of-tech-monopolism">Ronald Reagan, pioneer of tech monopolism</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#steering-with-the-windshield-wipers">Steering with the windshield wipers</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#surveillance-still-matters">Surveillance still matters</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#dignity-and-sanctuary">Dignity and sanctuary</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#afflicting-the-afflicted">Afflicting the afflicted</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#any-data-you-collect-and-retain-will-eventually-leak">Any data you collect and retain will eventually leak</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#critical-tech-exceptionalism-is-still-tech-exceptionalism">Critical tech exceptionalism is still tech exceptionalism</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#how-monopolies-not-mind-control-drive-surveillance-capitalism-the-snapchat-story">How monopolies, not mind control, drive surveillance capitalism: The
46 Snapchat story</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#a-monopoly-over-your-friends">A monopoly over your friends</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#fake-news-is-an-epistemological-crisis">Fake news is an epistemological crisis</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#tech-is-different">Tech is different</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#ownership-of-facts">Ownership of facts</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#persuasion-works-slowly">Persuasion works… slowly</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#paying-wont-help">Paying won’t help</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#an-ecology-moment-for-trustbusting">An <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">ecology</span> »</span> moment for trustbusting</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#make-big-tech-small-again">Make Big Tech small again</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#goto-10">20 GOTO 10</a></span></dt><dt><span class="sect1"><a href="#up-and-through">Up and through</a></span></dt></dl></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="the-net-of-a-thousand-lies"></a>The net of a thousand lies</h2></div></div></div><p>
47 The most surprising thing about the rebirth of flat Earthers in the 21st
48 century is just how widespread the evidence against them is. You can
49 understand how, centuries ago, people who’d never gained a high-enough
50 vantage point from which to see the Earth’s curvature might come to the
51 commonsense belief that the flat-seeming Earth was, indeed, flat.
52 </p><p>
53 But today, when elementary schools routinely dangle GoPro cameras from
54 balloons and loft them high enough to photograph the Earth’s curve — to say
55 nothing of the unexceptional sight of the curved Earth from an airplane
56 window — it takes a heroic effort to maintain the belief that the world is
57 flat.
58 </p><p>
59 Likewise for white nationalism and eugenics: In an age where you can become
60 a computational genomics datapoint by swabbing your cheek and mailing it to
61 a gene-sequencing company along with a modest sum of money, <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">race
62 science</span> »</span> has never been easier to refute.
63 </p><p>
64 We are living through a golden age of both readily available facts and
65 denial of those facts. Terrible ideas that have lingered on the fringes for
66 decades or even centuries have gone mainstream seemingly overnight.
67 </p><p>
68 When an obscure idea gains currency, there are only two things that can
69 explain its ascendance: Either the person expressing that idea has gotten a
70 lot better at stating their case, or the proposition has become harder to
71 deny in the face of mounting evidence. In other words, if we want people to
72 take climate change seriously, we can get a bunch of Greta Thunbergs to make
73 eloquent, passionate arguments from podiums, winning our hearts and minds,
74 or we can wait for flood, fire, broiling sun, and pandemics to make the case
75 for us. In practice, we’ll probably have to do some of both: The more we’re
76 boiling and burning and drowning and wasting away, the easier it will be for
77 the Greta Thunbergs of the world to convince us.
78 </p><p>
79 The arguments for ridiculous beliefs in odious conspiracies like
80 anti-vaccination, climate denial, a flat Earth, and eugenics are no better
81 than they were a generation ago. Indeed, they’re worse because they are
82 being pitched to people who have at least a background awareness of the
83 refuting facts.
84 </p><p>
85 Anti-vax has been around since the first vaccines, but the early
86 anti-vaxxers were pitching people who were less equipped to understand even
87 the most basic ideas from microbiology, and moreover, those people had not
88 witnessed the extermination of mass-murdering diseases like polio, smallpox,
89 and measles. Today’s anti-vaxxers are no more eloquent than their forebears,
90 and they have a much harder job.
91 </p><p>
92 So can these far-fetched conspiracy theorists really be succeeding on the
93 basis of superior arguments?
94 </p><p>
95 Some people think so. Today, there is a widespread belief that machine
96 learning and commercial surveillance can turn even the most fumble-tongued
97 conspiracy theorist into a svengali who can warp your perceptions and win
98 your belief by locating vulnerable people and then pitching them with
99 A.I.-refined arguments that bypass their rational faculties and turn
100 everyday people into flat Earthers, anti-vaxxers, or even Nazis. When the
101 RAND Corporation <a class="ulink" href="https://www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/research_reports/RR400/RR453/RAND_RR453.pdf" target="_top">blames
102 Facebook for <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">radicalization</span> »</span></a> and when Facebook’s role
103 in spreading coronavirus misinformation is <a class="ulink" href="https://secure.avaaz.org/campaign/en/facebook_threat_health/" target="_top">blamed on
104 its algorithm</a>, the implicit message is that machine learning and
105 surveillance are causing the changes in our consensus about what’s true.
106 </p><p>
107 After all, in a world where sprawling and incoherent conspiracy theories
108 like Pizzagate and its successor, QAnon, have widespread followings,
109 <span class="emphasis"><em>something</em></span> must be afoot.
110 </p><p>
111 But what if there’s another explanation? What if it’s the material
112 circumstances, and not the arguments, that are making the difference for
113 these conspiracy pitchmen? What if the trauma of living through
114 <span class="emphasis"><em>real conspiracies</em></span> all around us — conspiracies among
115 wealthy people, their lobbyists, and lawmakers to bury inconvenient facts
116 and evidence of wrongdoing (these conspiracies are commonly known as
117 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">corruption</span> »</span>) — is making people vulnerable to conspiracy
118 theories?
119 </p><p>
120 If it’s trauma and not contagion — material conditions and not ideology —
121 that is making the difference today and enabling a rise of repulsive
122 misinformation in the face of easily observed facts, that doesn’t mean our
123 computer networks are blameless. They’re still doing the heavy work of
124 locating vulnerable people and guiding them through a series of
125 ever-more-extreme ideas and communities.
126 </p><p>
127 Belief in conspiracy is a raging fire that has done real damage and poses
128 real danger to our planet and species, from epidemics <a class="ulink" href="https://www.cdc.gov/measles/cases-outbreaks.html" target="_top">kicked off by vaccine
129 denial</a> to genocides <a class="ulink" href="https://www.nytimes.com/2018/10/15/technology/myanmar-facebook-genocide.html" target="_top">kicked
130 off by racist conspiracies</a> to planetary meltdown caused by
131 denial-inspired climate inaction. Our world is on fire, and so we have to
132 put the fires out — to figure out how to help people see the truth of the
133 world through the conspiracies they’ve been confused by.
134 </p><p>
135 But firefighting is reactive. We need fire
136 <span class="emphasis"><em>prevention</em></span>. We need to strike at the traumatic material
137 conditions that make people vulnerable to the contagion of conspiracy. Here,
138 too, tech has a role to play.
139 </p><p>
140 There’s no shortage of proposals to address this. From the EU’s <a class="ulink" href="https://edri.org/tag/terreg/" target="_top">Terrorist Content Regulation</a>,
141 which requires platforms to police and remove <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">extremist</span> »</span>
142 content, to the U.S. proposals to <a class="ulink" href="https://www.eff.org/deeplinks/2020/03/earn-it-act-violates-constitution" target="_top">force
143 tech companies to spy on their users</a> and hold them liable <a class="ulink" href="https://www.natlawreview.com/article/repeal-cda-section-230" target="_top">for their
144 users’ bad speech</a>, there’s a lot of energy to force tech companies
145 to solve the problems they created.
146 </p><p>
147 There’s a critical piece missing from the debate, though. All these
148 solutions assume that tech companies are a fixture, that their dominance
149 over the internet is a permanent fact. Proposals to replace Big Tech with a
150 more diffused, pluralistic internet are nowhere to be found. Worse: The
151 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">solutions</span> »</span> on the table today <span class="emphasis"><em>require</em></span> Big
152 Tech to stay big because only the very largest companies can afford to
153 implement the systems these laws demand.
154 </p><p>
155 Figuring out what we want our tech to look like is crucial if we’re going to
156 get out of this mess. Today, we’re at a crossroads where we’re trying to
157 figure out if we want to fix the Big Tech companies that dominate our
158 internet or if we want to fix the internet itself by unshackling it from Big
159 Tech’s stranglehold. We can’t do both, so we have to choose.
160 </p><p>
161 I want us to choose wisely. Taming Big Tech is integral to fixing the
162 Internet, and for that, we need digital rights activism.
163 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="digital-rights-activism-a-quarter-century-on"></a>Digital rights activism, a quarter-century on</h2></div></div></div><p>
164 Digital rights activism is more than 30 years old now. The Electronic
165 Frontier Foundation turned 30 this year; the Free Software Foundation
166 launched in 1985. For most of the history of the movement, the most
167 prominent criticism leveled against it was that it was irrelevant: The real
168 activist causes were real-world causes (think of the skepticism when <a class="ulink" href="https://www.loc.gov/law/foreign-news/article/finland-legal-right-to-broadband-for-all-citizens/#:~:text=Global%20Legal%20Monitor,-Home%20%7C%20Search%20%7C%20Browse&amp;text=(July%206%2C%202010)%20On,connection%20100%20MBPS%20by%202015." target="_top">Finland
169 declared broadband a human right in 2010</a>), and real-world activism
170 was shoe-leather activism (think of Malcolm Gladwell’s <a class="ulink" href="https://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2010/10/04/small-change-malcolm-gladwell" target="_top">contempt
171 for <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">clicktivism</span> »</span></a>). But as tech has grown more central
172 to our daily lives, these accusations of irrelevance have given way first to
173 accusations of insincerity (<span class="quote">« <span class="quote">You only care about tech because you’re
174 <a class="ulink" href="https://www.ipwatchdog.com/2018/06/04/report-engine-eff-shills-google-patent-reform/id=98007/" target="_top">shilling
175 for tech companies</a></span> »</span>) to accusations of negligence (<span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Why
176 didn’t you foresee that tech could be such a destructive force?</span> »</span>).
177 But digital rights activism is right where it’s always been: looking out for
178 the humans in a world where tech is inexorably taking over.
179 </p><p>
180 The latest version of this critique comes in the form of <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">surveillance
181 capitalism,</span> »</span> a term coined by business professor Shoshana Zuboff in
182 her long and influential 2019 book, <span class="emphasis"><em>The Age of Surveillance
183 Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at the New Frontier of
184 Power</em></span>. Zuboff argues that <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">surveillance capitalism</span> »</span>
185 is a unique creature of the tech industry and that it is unlike any other
186 abusive commercial practice in history, one that is <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">constituted by
187 unexpected and often illegible mechanisms of extraction, commodification,
188 and control that effectively exile persons from their own behavior while
189 producing new markets of behavioral prediction and
190 modification. Surveillance capitalism challenges democratic norms and
191 departs in key ways from the centuries-long evolution of market
192 capitalism.</span> »</span> It is a new and deadly form of capitalism, a
193 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism,</span> »</span> and our lack of understanding of its unique
194 capabilities and dangers represents an existential, species-wide
195 threat. She’s right that capitalism today threatens our species, and she’s
196 right that tech poses unique challenges to our species and civilization, but
197 she’s really wrong about how tech is different and why it threatens our
198 species.
199 </p><p>
200 What’s more, I think that her incorrect diagnosis will lead us down a path
201 that ends up making Big Tech stronger, not weaker. We need to take down Big
202 Tech, and to do that, we need to start by correctly identifying the problem.
203 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="tech-exceptionalism-then-and-now"></a>Tech exceptionalism, then and now</h2></div></div></div><p>
204 Early critics of the digital rights movement — perhaps best represented by
205 campaigning organizations like the Electronic Frontier Foundation, the Free
206 Software Foundation, Public Knowledge, and others that focused on preserving
207 and enhancing basic human rights in the digital realm — damned activists for
208 practicing <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">tech exceptionalism.</span> »</span> Around the turn of the
209 millennium, serious people ridiculed any claim that tech policy mattered in
210 the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">real world.</span> »</span> Claims that tech rules had implications for
211 speech, association, privacy, search and seizure, and fundamental rights and
212 equities were treated as ridiculous, an elevation of the concerns of sad
213 nerds arguing about <span class="emphasis"><em>Star Trek</em></span> on bulletin board systems
214 above the struggles of the Freedom Riders, Nelson Mandela, or the Warsaw
215 ghetto uprising.
216 </p><p>
217 In the decades since, accusations of <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">tech exceptionalism</span> »</span> have
218 only sharpened as tech’s role in everyday life has expanded: Now that tech
219 has infiltrated every corner of our life and our online lives have been
220 monopolized by a handful of giants, defenders of digital freedoms are
221 accused of carrying water for Big Tech, providing cover for its
222 self-interested negligence (or worse, nefarious plots).
223 </p><p>
224 From my perspective, the digital rights movement has remained stationary
225 while the rest of the world has moved. From the earliest days, the
226 movement’s concern was users and the toolsmiths who provided the code they
227 needed to realize their fundamental rights. Digital rights activists only
228 cared about companies to the extent that companies were acting to uphold
229 users’ rights (or, just as often, when companies were acting so foolishly
230 that they threatened to bring down new rules that would also make it harder
231 for good actors to help users).
232 </p><p>
233 The <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">surveillance capitalism</span> »</span> critique recasts the digital
234 rights movement in a new light again: not as alarmists who overestimate the
235 importance of their shiny toys nor as shills for big tech but as serene
236 deck-chair rearrangers whose long-standing activism is a liability because
237 it makes them incapable of perceiving novel threats as they continue to
238 fight the last century’s tech battles.
239 </p><p>
240 But tech exceptionalism is a sin no matter who practices it.
241 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="dont-believe-the-hype"></a>Don’t believe the hype</h2></div></div></div><p>
242 You’ve probably heard that <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">if you’re not paying for the product,
243 you’re the product.</span> »</span> As we’ll see below, that’s true, if incomplete.
244 But what is <span class="emphasis"><em>absolutely</em></span> true is that ad-driven Big
245 Tech’s customers are advertisers, and what companies like Google and
246 Facebook sell is their ability to convince <span class="emphasis"><em>you</em></span> to buy
247 stuff. Big Tech’s product is persuasion. The services — social media, search
248 engines, maps, messaging, and more — are delivery systems for persuasion.
249 </p><p>
250 The fear of surveillance capitalism starts from the (correct) presumption
251 that everything Big Tech says about itself is probably a lie. But the
252 surveillance capitalism critique makes an exception for the claims Big Tech
253 makes in its sales literature — the breathless hype in the pitches to
254 potential advertisers online and in ad-tech seminars about the efficacy of
255 its products: It assumes that Big Tech is as good at influencing us as they
256 claim they are when they’re selling influencing products to credulous
257 customers. That’s a mistake because sales literature is not a reliable
258 indicator of a product’s efficacy.
259 </p><p>
260 Surveillance capitalism assumes that because advertisers buy a lot of what
261 Big Tech is selling, Big Tech must be selling something real. But Big Tech’s
262 massive sales could just as easily be the result of a popular delusion or
263 something even more pernicious: monopolistic control over our communications
264 and commerce.
265 </p><p>
266 Being watched changes your behavior, and not for the better. It creates
267 risks for our social progress. Zuboff’s book features beautifully wrought
268 explanations of these phenomena. But Zuboff also claims that surveillance
269 literally robs us of our free will — that when our personal data is mixed
270 with machine learning, it creates a system of persuasion so devastating that
271 we are helpless before it. That is, Facebook uses an algorithm to analyze
272 the data it nonconsensually extracts from your daily life and uses it to
273 customize your feed in ways that get you to buy stuff. It is a mind-control
274 ray out of a 1950s comic book, wielded by mad scientists whose
275 supercomputers guarantee them perpetual and total world domination.
276 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="what-is-persuasion"></a>What is persuasion?</h2></div></div></div><p>
277 To understand why you shouldn’t worry about mind-control rays — but why you
278 <span class="emphasis"><em>should</em></span> worry about surveillance
279 <span class="emphasis"><em>and</em></span> Big Tech — we must start by unpacking what we mean
280 by <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">persuasion.</span> »</span>
281 </p><p>
282 Google, Facebook, and other surveillance capitalists promise their customers
283 (the advertisers) that if they use machine-learning tools trained on
284 unimaginably large data sets of nonconsensually harvested personal
285 information, they will be able to uncover ways to bypass the rational
286 faculties of the public and direct their behavior, creating a stream of
287 purchases, votes, and other desired outcomes.
288 </p><div class="blockquote"><blockquote class="blockquote"><p>
289 The impact of dominance far exceeds the impact of manipulation and should be
290 central to our analysis and any remedies we seek.
291 </p></blockquote></div><p>
292 But there’s little evidence that this is happening. Instead, the predictions
293 that surveillance capitalism delivers to its customers are much less
294 impressive. Rather than finding ways to bypass our rational faculties,
295 surveillance capitalists like Mark Zuckerberg mostly do one or more of three
296 things:
297 </p><div class="sect2"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h3 class="title"><a name="segmenting"></a>1. Segmenting</h3></div></div></div><p>
298 If you’re selling diapers, you have better luck if you pitch them to people
299 in maternity wards. Not everyone who enters or leaves a maternity ward just
300 had a baby, and not everyone who just had a baby is in the market for
301 diapers. But having a baby is a really reliable correlate of being in the
302 market for diapers, and being in a maternity ward is highly correlated with
303 having a baby. Hence diaper ads around maternity wards (and even pitchmen
304 for baby products, who haunt maternity wards with baskets full of freebies).
305 </p><p>
306 Le capitalisme de surveillance se segmente par milliard. Les vendeurs de
307 couches peuvent aller bien au-delà des personnes dans les maternités (bien
308 qu’ils puissent le faire aussi, avec des choses comme les annonces mobiles
309 basées sur la localisation). Ils peuvent vous cibler selon que vous lisez
310 des articles sur l’éducation des enfants, les couches ou une foule d’autres
311 sujets, et l’exploration de données peut suggérer des mots-clés non évidents
312 sur lesquels faire de la publicité. Ils peuvent vous cibler en fonction des
313 articles que vous avez récemment lus. Ils peuvent vous cibler en fonction de
314 ce que vous avez récemment acheté. Ils peuvent vous cibler selon que vous
315 recevez des courriels ou des messages privés sur ces sujets – ou même si
316 vous en parlez à haute voix (bien que Facebook et autres affirment de
317 manière convaincante que cela ne se produit pas encore).
318 </p><p>
319 This is seriously creepy.
320 </p><p>
321 But it’s not mind control.
322 </p><p>
323 It doesn’t deprive you of your free will. It doesn’t trick you.
324 </p><p>
325 Think of how surveillance capitalism works in politics. Surveillance
326 capitalist companies sell political operatives the power to locate people
327 who might be receptive to their pitch. Candidates campaigning on finance
328 industry corruption seek people struggling with debt; candidates campaigning
329 on xenophobia seek out racists. Political operatives have always targeted
330 their message whether their intentions were honorable or not: Union
331 organizers set up pitches at factory gates, and white supremacists hand out
332 fliers at John Birch Society meetings.
333 </p><p>
334 But this is an inexact and thus wasteful practice. The union organizer can’t
335 know which worker to approach on the way out of the factory gates and may
336 waste their time on a covert John Birch Society member; the white
337 supremacist doesn’t know which of the Birchers are so delusional that making
338 it to a meeting is as much as they can manage and which ones might be
339 convinced to cross the country to carry a tiki torch through the streets of
340 Charlottesville, Virginia.
341 </p><p>
342 Because targeting improves the yields on political pitches, it can
343 accelerate the pace of political upheaval by making it possible for everyone
344 who has secretly wished for the toppling of an autocrat — or just an 11-term
345 incumbent politician — to find everyone else who feels the same way at very
346 low cost. This has been critical to the rapid crystallization of recent
347 political movements including Black Lives Matter and Occupy Wall Street as
348 well as less savory players like the far-right white nationalist movements
349 that marched in Charlottesville.
350 </p><p>
351 It’s important to differentiate this kind of political organizing from
352 influence campaigns; finding people who secretly agree with you isn’t the
353 same as convincing people to agree with you. The rise of phenomena like
354 nonbinary or otherwise nonconforming gender identities is often
355 characterized by reactionaries as the result of online brainwashing
356 campaigns that convince impressionable people that they have been secretly
357 queer all along.
358 </p><p>
359 But the personal accounts of those who have come out tell a different story
360 where people who long harbored a secret about their gender were emboldened
361 by others coming forward and where people who knew that they were different
362 but lacked a vocabulary for discussing that difference learned the right
363 words from these low-cost means of finding people and learning about their
364 ideas.
365 </p></div><div class="sect2"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h3 class="title"><a name="deception"></a>2. Deception</h3></div></div></div><p>
366 Lies and fraud are pernicious, and surveillance capitalism supercharges them
367 through targeting. If you want to sell a fraudulent payday loan or subprime
368 mortgage, surveillance capitalism can help you find people who are both
369 desperate and unsophisticated and thus receptive to your pitch. This
370 accounts for the rise of many phenomena, like multilevel marketing schemes,
371 in which deceptive claims about potential earnings and the efficacy of sales
372 techniques are targeted at desperate people by advertising against search
373 queries that indicate, for example, someone struggling with ill-advised
374 loans.
375 </p><p>
376 Surveillance capitalism also abets fraud by making it easy to locate other
377 people who have been similarly deceived, forming a community of people who
378 reinforce one another’s false beliefs. Think of <a class="ulink" href="https://www.vulture.com/2020/01/the-dream-podcast-review.html" target="_top">the
379 forums</a> where people who are being victimized by multilevel marketing
380 frauds gather to trade tips on how to improve their luck in peddling the
381 product.
382 </p><p>
383 Sometimes, online deception involves replacing someone’s correct beliefs
384 with incorrect ones, as it does in the anti-vaccination movement, whose
385 victims are often people who start out believing in vaccines but are
386 convinced by seemingly plausible evidence that leads them into the false
387 belief that vaccines are harmful.
388 </p><p>
389 But it’s much more common for fraud to succeed when it doesn’t have to
390 displace a true belief. When my daughter contracted head lice at daycare,
391 one of the daycare workers told me I could get rid of them by treating her
392 hair and scalp with olive oil. I didn’t know anything about head lice, and I
393 assumed that the daycare worker did, so I tried it (it didn’t work, and it
394 doesn’t work). It’s easy to end up with false beliefs when you simply don’t
395 know any better and when those beliefs are conveyed by someone who seems to
396 know what they’re doing.
397 </p><p>
398 This is pernicious and difficult — and it’s also the kind of thing the
399 internet can help guard against by making true information available,
400 especially in a form that exposes the underlying deliberations among parties
401 with sharply divergent views, such as Wikipedia. But it’s not brainwashing;
402 it’s fraud. In the <a class="ulink" href="https://datasociety.net/library/data-voids/" target="_top">majority of cases</a>,
403 the victims of these fraud campaigns have an informational void filled in
404 the customary way, by consulting a seemingly reliable source. If I look up
405 the length of the Brooklyn Bridge and learn that it is 5,800 feet long, but
406 in reality, it is 5,989 feet long, the underlying deception is a problem,
407 but it’s a problem with a simple remedy. It’s a very different problem from
408 the anti-vax issue in which someone’s true belief is displaced by a false
409 one by means of sophisticated persuasion.
410 </p></div><div class="sect2"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h3 class="title"><a name="domination"></a>3. Domination</h3></div></div></div><p>
411 Surveillance capitalism is the result of monopoly. Monopoly is the cause,
412 and surveillance capitalism and its negative outcomes are the effects of
413 monopoly. I’ll get into this in depth later, but for now, suffice it to say
414 that the tech industry has grown up with a radical theory of antitrust that
415 has allowed companies to grow by merging with their rivals, buying up their
416 nascent competitors, and expanding to control whole market verticals.
417 </p><p>
418 One example of how monopolism aids in persuasion is through dominance:
419 Google makes editorial decisions about its algorithms that determine the
420 sort order of the responses to our queries. If a cabal of fraudsters have
421 set out to trick the world into thinking that the Brooklyn Bridge is 5,800
422 feet long, and if Google gives a high search rank to this group in response
423 to queries like <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">How long is the Brooklyn Bridge?</span> »</span> then the
424 first eight or 10 screens’ worth of Google results could be wrong. And since
425 most people don’t go beyond the first couple of results — let alone the
426 first <span class="emphasis"><em>page</em></span> of results — Google’s choice means that many
427 people will be deceived.
428 </p><p>
429 Google’s dominance over search — more than 86% of web searches are performed
430 through Google — means that the way it orders its search results has an
431 outsized effect on public beliefs. Ironically, Google claims this is why it
432 can’t afford to have any transparency in its algorithm design: Google’s
433 search dominance makes the results of its sorting too important to risk
434 telling the world how it arrives at those results lest some bad actor
435 discover a flaw in the ranking system and exploit it to push its point of
436 view to the top of the search results. There’s an obvious remedy to a
437 company that is too big to audit: break it up into smaller pieces.
438 </p><p>
439 Zuboff calls surveillance capitalism a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism</span> »</span> whose
440 data-hoarding and machine-learning techniques rob us of our free will. But
441 influence campaigns that seek to displace existing, correct beliefs with
442 false ones have an effect that is small and temporary while monopolistic
443 dominance over informational systems has massive, enduring
444 effects. Controlling the results to the world’s search queries means
445 controlling access both to arguments and their rebuttals and, thus, control
446 over much of the world’s beliefs. If our concern is how corporations are
447 foreclosing on our ability to make up our own minds and determine our own
448 futures, the impact of dominance far exceeds the impact of manipulation and
449 should be central to our analysis and any remedies we seek.
450 </p></div><div class="sect2"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h3 class="title"><a name="bypassing-our-rational-faculties"></a>4. Bypassing our rational faculties</h3></div></div></div><p>
451 <span class="emphasis"><em>This</em></span> is the good stuff: using machine learning,
452 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">dark patterns,</span> »</span> engagement hacking, and other techniques to
453 get us to do things that run counter to our better judgment. This is mind
454 control.
455 </p><p>
456 Some of these techniques have proven devastatingly effective (if only in the
457 short term). The use of countdown timers on a purchase completion page can
458 create a sense of urgency that causes you to ignore the nagging internal
459 voice suggesting that you should shop around or sleep on your decision. The
460 use of people from your social graph in ads can provide <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">social
461 proof</span> »</span> that a purchase is worth making. Even the auction system
462 pioneered by eBay is calculated to play on our cognitive blind spots,
463 letting us feel like we <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">own</span> »</span> something because we bid on it,
464 thus encouraging us to bid again when we are outbid to ensure that
465 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">our</span> »</span> things stay ours.
466 </p><p>
467 Games are extraordinarily good at this. <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Free to play</span> »</span> games
468 manipulate us through many techniques, such as presenting players with a
469 series of smoothly escalating challenges that create a sense of mastery and
470 accomplishment but which sharply transition into a set of challenges that
471 are impossible to overcome without paid upgrades. Add some social proof to
472 the mix — a stream of notifications about how well your friends are faring —
473 and before you know it, you’re buying virtual power-ups to get to the next
474 level.
475 </p><p>
476 Companies have risen and fallen on these techniques, and the
477 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">fallen</span> »</span> part is worth paying attention to. In general, living
478 things adapt to stimulus: Something that is very compelling or noteworthy
479 when you first encounter it fades with repetition until you stop noticing it
480 altogether. Consider the refrigerator hum that irritates you when it starts
481 up but disappears into the background so thoroughly that you only notice it
482 when it stops again.
483 </p><p>
484 That’s why behavioral conditioning uses <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">intermittent reinforcement
485 schedules.</span> »</span> Instead of giving you a steady drip of encouragement or
486 setbacks, games and gamified services scatter rewards on a randomized
487 schedule — often enough to keep you interested and random enough that you
488 can never quite find the pattern that would make it boring.
489 </p><p>
490 Intermittent reinforcement is a powerful behavioral tool, but it also
491 represents a collective action problem for surveillance capitalism. The
492 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">engagement techniques</span> »</span> invented by the behaviorists of
493 surveillance capitalist companies are quickly copied across the whole sector
494 so that what starts as a mysteriously compelling fillip in the design of a
495 service—like <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">pull to refresh</span> »</span> or alerts when someone likes
496 your posts or side quests that your characters get invited to while in the
497 midst of main quests—quickly becomes dully ubiquitous. The
498 impossible-to-nail-down nonpattern of randomized drips from your phone
499 becomes a grey-noise wall of sound as every single app and site starts to
500 make use of whatever seems to be working at the time.
501 </p><p>
502 From the surveillance capitalist’s point of view, our adaptive capacity is
503 like a harmful bacterium that deprives it of its food source — our attention
504 — and novel techniques for snagging that attention are like new antibiotics
505 that can be used to breach our defenses and destroy our
506 self-determination. And there <span class="emphasis"><em>are</em></span> techniques like
507 that. Who can forget the Great Zynga Epidemic, when all of our friends were
508 caught in <span class="emphasis"><em>FarmVille</em></span>’s endless, mindless dopamine loops?
509 But every new attention-commanding technique is jumped on by the whole
510 industry and used so indiscriminately that antibiotic resistance sets
511 in. Given enough repetition, almost all of us develop immunity to even the
512 most powerful techniques — by 2013, two years after Zynga’s peak, its user
513 base had halved.
514 </p><p>
515 Not everyone, of course. Some people never adapt to stimulus, just as some
516 people never stop hearing the hum of the refrigerator. This is why most
517 people who are exposed to slot machines play them for a while and then move
518 on while a small and tragic minority liquidate their kids’ college funds,
519 buy adult diapers, and position themselves in front of a machine until they
520 collapse.
521 </p><p>
522 But surveillance capitalism’s margins on behavioral modification
523 suck. Tripling the rate at which someone buys a widget sounds great <a class="ulink" href="https://www.forbes.com/sites/priceonomics/2018/03/09/the-advertising-conversion-rates-for-every-major-tech-platform/#2f6a67485957" target="_top">unless
524 the base rate is way less than 1%</a> with an improved rate of… still
525 less than 1%. Even penny slot machines pull down pennies for every spin
526 while surveillance capitalism rakes in infinitesimal penny fractions.
527 </p><p>
528 Slot machines’ high returns mean that they can be profitable just by
529 draining the fortunes of the small rump of people who are pathologically
530 vulnerable to them and unable to adapt to their tricks. But surveillance
531 capitalism can’t survive on the fractional pennies it brings down from that
532 vulnerable sliver — that’s why, after the Great Zynga Epidemic had finally
533 burned itself out, the small number of still-addicted players left behind
534 couldn’t sustain it as a global phenomenon. And new powerful attention
535 weapons aren’t easy to find, as is evidenced by the long years since the
536 last time Zynga had a hit. Despite the hundreds of millions of dollars that
537 Zynga has to spend on developing new tools to blast through our adaptation,
538 it has never managed to repeat the lucky accident that let it snag so much
539 of our attention for a brief moment in 2009. Powerhouses like Supercell have
540 fared a little better, but they are rare and throw away many failures for
541 every success.
542 </p><p>
543 The vulnerability of small segments of the population to dramatic, efficient
544 corporate manipulation is a real concern that’s worthy of our attention and
545 energy. But it’s not an existential threat to society.
546 </p></div></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="if-data-is-the-new-oil-then-surveillance-capitalisms-engine-has-a-leak"></a>If data is the new oil, then surveillance capitalism’s engine has a leak</h2></div></div></div><p>
547 This adaptation problem offers an explanation for one of surveillance
548 capitalism’s most alarming traits: its relentless hunger for data and its
549 endless expansion of data-gathering capabilities through the spread of
550 sensors, online surveillance, and acquisition of data streams from third
551 parties.
552 </p><p>
553 Zuboff observes this phenomenon and concludes that data must be very
554 valuable if surveillance capitalism is so hungry for it. (In her words:
555 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Just as industrial capitalism was driven to the continuous
556 intensification of the means of production, so surveillance capitalists and
557 their market players are now locked into the continuous intensification of
558 the means of behavioral modification and the gathering might of
559 instrumentarian power.</span> »</span>) But what if the voracious appetite is
560 because data has such a short half-life — because people become inured so
561 quickly to new, data-driven persuasion techniques — that the companies are
562 locked in an arms race with our limbic system? What if it’s all a Red
563 Queen’s race where they have to run ever faster — collect ever-more data —
564 just to stay in the same spot?
565 </p><p>
566 Of course, all of Big Tech’s persuasion techniques work in concert with one
567 another, and collecting data is useful beyond mere behavioral trickery.
568 </p><p>
569 If someone wants to recruit you to buy a refrigerator or join a pogrom, they
570 might use profiling and targeting to send messages to people they judge to
571 be good sales prospects. The messages themselves may be deceptive, making
572 claims about things you’re not very knowledgeable about (food safety and
573 energy efficiency or eugenics and historical claims about racial
574 superiority). They might use search engine optimization and/or armies of
575 fake reviewers and commenters and/or paid placement to dominate the
576 discourse so that any search for further information takes you back to their
577 messages. And finally, they may refine the different pitches using machine
578 learning and other techniques to figure out what kind of pitch works best on
579 someone like you.
580 </p><p>
581 Each phase of this process benefits from surveillance: The more data they
582 have, the more precisely they can profile you and target you with specific
583 messages. Think of how you’d sell a fridge if you knew that the warranty on
584 your prospect’s fridge just expired and that they were expecting a tax
585 rebate in April.
586 </p><p>
587 Also, the more data they have, the better they can craft deceptive messages
588 — if I know that you’re into genealogy, I might not try to feed you
589 pseudoscience about genetic differences between <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">races,</span> »</span>
590 sticking instead to conspiratorial secret histories of <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">demographic
591 replacement</span> »</span> and the like.
592 </p><p>
593 Facebook also helps you locate people who have the same odious or antisocial
594 views as you. It makes it possible to find other people who want to carry
595 tiki torches through the streets of Charlottesville in Confederate
596 cosplay. It can help you find other people who want to join your militia and
597 go to the border to look for undocumented migrants to terrorize. It can help
598 you find people who share your belief that vaccines are poison and that the
599 Earth is flat.
600 </p><p>
601 There is one way in which targeted advertising uniquely benefits those
602 advocating for socially unacceptable causes: It is invisible. Racism is
603 widely geographically dispersed, and there are few places where racists —
604 and only racists — gather. This is similar to the problem of selling
605 refrigerators in that potential refrigerator purchasers are geographically
606 dispersed and there are few places where you can buy an ad that will be
607 primarily seen by refrigerator customers. But buying a refrigerator is
608 socially acceptable while being a Nazi is not, so you can buy a billboard or
609 advertise in the newspaper sports section for your refrigerator business,
610 and the only potential downside is that your ad will be seen by a lot of
611 people who don’t want refrigerators, resulting in a lot of wasted expense.
612 </p><p>
613 But even if you wanted to advertise your Nazi movement on a billboard or
614 prime-time TV or the sports section, you would struggle to find anyone
615 willing to sell you the space for your ad partly because they disagree with
616 your views and partly because they fear censure (boycott, reputational
617 damage, etc.) from other people who disagree with your views.
618 </p><p>
619 Targeted ads solve this problem: On the internet, every ad unit can be
620 different for every person, meaning that you can buy ads that are only shown
621 to people who appear to be Nazis and not to people who hate Nazis. When
622 there’s spillover — when someone who hates racism is shown a racist
623 recruiting ad — there is some fallout; the platform or publication might get
624 an angry public or private denunciation. But the nature of the risk assumed
625 by an online ad buyer is different than the risks to a traditional publisher
626 or billboard owner who might want to run a Nazi ad.
627 </p><p>
628 Online ads are placed by algorithms that broker between a diverse ecosystem
629 of self-serve ad platforms that anyone can buy an ad through, so the Nazi ad
630 that slips onto your favorite online publication isn’t seen as their moral
631 failing but rather as a failure in some distant, upstream ad supplier. When
632 a publication gets a complaint about an offensive ad that’s appearing in one
633 of its units, it can take some steps to block that ad, but the Nazi might
634 buy a slightly different ad from a different broker serving the same
635 unit. And in any event, internet users increasingly understand that when
636 they see an ad, it’s likely that the advertiser did not choose that
637 publication and that the publication has no idea who its advertisers are.
638 </p><p>
639 These layers of indirection between advertisers and publishers serve as
640 moral buffers: Today’s moral consensus is largely that publishers shouldn’t
641 be held responsible for the ads that appear on their pages because they’re
642 not actively choosing to put those ads there. Because of this, Nazis are
643 able to overcome significant barriers to organizing their movement.
644 </p><p>
645 Data has a complex relationship with domination. Being able to spy on your
646 customers can alert you to their preferences for your rivals and allow you
647 to head off your rivals at the pass.
648 </p><p>
649 More importantly, if you can dominate the information space while also
650 gathering data, then you make other deceptive tactics stronger because it’s
651 harder to break out of the web of deceit you’re spinning. Domination — that
652 is, ultimately becoming a monopoly — and not the data itself is the
653 supercharger that makes every tactic worth pursuing because monopolistic
654 domination deprives your target of an escape route.
655 </p><p>
656 If you’re a Nazi who wants to ensure that your prospects primarily see
657 deceptive, confirming information when they search for more, you can improve
658 your odds by seeding the search terms they use through your initial
659 communications. You don’t need to own the top 10 results for <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">voter
660 suppression</span> »</span> if you can convince your marks to confine their search
661 terms to <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">voter fraud,</span> »</span> which throws up a very different set of
662 search results.
663 </p><p>
664 Surveillance capitalists are like stage mentalists who claim that their
665 extraordinary insights into human behavior let them guess the word that you
666 wrote down and folded up in your pocket but who really use shills, hidden
667 cameras, sleight of hand, and brute-force memorization to amaze you.
668 </p><p>
669 Or perhaps they’re more like pick-up artists, the misogynistic cult that
670 promises to help awkward men have sex with women by teaching them
671 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">neurolinguistic programming</span> »</span> phrases, body language
672 techniques, and psychological manipulation tactics like
673 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">negging</span> »</span> — offering unsolicited negative feedback to women to
674 lower their self-esteem and prick their interest.
675 </p><p>
676 Some pick-up artists eventually manage to convince women to go home with
677 them, but it’s not because these men have figured out how to bypass women’s
678 critical faculties. Rather, pick-up artists’ <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">success</span> »</span> stories
679 are a mix of women who were incapable of giving consent, women who were
680 coerced, women who were intoxicated, self-destructive women, and a few women
681 who were sober and in command of their faculties but who didn’t realize
682 straightaway that they were with terrible men but rectified the error as
683 soon as they could.
684 </p><p>
685 Pick-up artists <span class="emphasis"><em>believe</em></span> they have figured out a secret
686 back door that bypasses women’s critical faculties, but they haven’t. Many
687 of the tactics they deploy, like negging, became the butt of jokes (just
688 like people joke about bad ad targeting), and there’s a good chance that
689 anyone they try these tactics on will immediately recognize them and dismiss
690 the men who use them as irredeemable losers.
691 </p><p>
692 Pick-up artists are proof that people can believe they have developed a
693 system of mind control <span class="emphasis"><em>even when it doesn’t
694 work</em></span>. Pick-up artists simply exploit the fact that
695 one-in-a-million chances can come through for you if you make a million
696 attempts, and then they assume that the other 999,999 times, they simply
697 performed the technique incorrectly and commit themselves to doing better
698 next time. There’s only one group of people who find pick-up artist lore
699 reliably convincing: other would-be pick-up artists whose anxiety and
700 insecurity make them vulnerable to scammers and delusional men who convince
701 them that if they pay for tutelage and follow instructions, then they will
702 someday succeed. Pick-up artists assume they fail to entice women because
703 they are bad at being pick-up artists, not because pick-up artistry is
704 bullshit. Pick-up artists are bad at selling themselves to women, but
705 they’re much better at selling themselves to men who pay to learn the
706 secrets of pick-up artistry.
707 </p><p>
708 Department store pioneer John Wanamaker is said to have lamented,
709 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Half the money I spend on advertising is wasted; the trouble is I
710 don’t know which half.</span> »</span> The fact that Wanamaker thought that only
711 half of his advertising spending was wasted is a tribute to the
712 persuasiveness of advertising executives, who are <span class="emphasis"><em>much</em></span>
713 better at convincing potential clients to buy their services than they are
714 at convincing the general public to buy their clients’ wares.
715 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="what-is-facebook"></a>What is Facebook?</h2></div></div></div><p>
716 Facebook is heralded as the origin of all of our modern plagues, and it’s
717 not hard to see why. Some tech companies want to lock their users in but
718 make their money by monopolizing access to the market for apps for their
719 devices and gouging them on prices rather than by spying on them (like
720 Apple). Some companies don’t care about locking in users because they’ve
721 figured out how to spy on them no matter where they are and what they’re
722 doing and can turn that surveillance into money (Google). Facebook alone
723 among the Western tech giants has built a business based on locking in its
724 users <span class="emphasis"><em>and</em></span> spying on them all the time.
725 </p><p>
726 Facebook’s surveillance regime is really without parallel in the Western
727 world. Though Facebook tries to prevent itself from being visible on the
728 public web, hiding most of what goes on there from people unless they’re
729 logged into Facebook, the company has nevertheless booby-trapped the entire
730 web with surveillance tools in the form of Facebook <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Like</span> »</span>
731 buttons that web publishers include on their sites to boost their Facebook
732 profiles. Facebook also makes various libraries and other useful code
733 snippets available to web publishers that act as surveillance tendrils on
734 the sites where they’re used, funneling information about visitors to the
735 site — newspapers, dating sites, message boards — to Facebook.
736 </p><div class="blockquote"><blockquote class="blockquote"><p>
737 Big Tech is able to practice surveillance not just because it is tech but
738 because it is <span class="emphasis"><em>big</em></span>.
739 </p></blockquote></div><p>
740 Facebook offers similar tools to app developers, so the apps — games, fart
741 machines, business review services, apps for keeping abreast of your kid’s
742 schooling — you use will send information about your activities to Facebook
743 even if you don’t have a Facebook account and even if you don’t download or
744 use Facebook apps. On top of all that, Facebook buys data from third-party
745 brokers on shopping habits, physical location, use of <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">loyalty</span> »</span>
746 programs, financial transactions, etc., and cross-references that with the
747 dossiers it develops on activity on Facebook and with apps and the public
748 web.
749 </p><p>
750 Though it’s easy to integrate the web with Facebook — linking to news
751 stories and such — Facebook products are generally not available to be
752 integrated back into the web itself. You can embed a tweet in a Facebook
753 post, but if you embed a Facebook post in a tweet, you just get a link back
754 to Facebook and must log in before you can see it. Facebook has used extreme
755 technological and legal countermeasures to prevent rivals from allowing
756 their users to embed Facebook snippets in competing services or to create
757 alternative interfaces to Facebook that merge your Facebook inbox with those
758 of other services that you use.
759 </p><p>
760 And Facebook is incredibly popular, with 2.3 billion claimed users (though
761 many believe this figure to be inflated). Facebook has been used to organize
762 genocidal pogroms, racist riots, anti-vaccination movements, flat Earth
763 cults, and the political lives of some of the world’s ugliest, most brutal
764 autocrats. There are some really alarming things going on in the world, and
765 Facebook is implicated in many of them, so it’s easy to conclude that these
766 bad things are the result of Facebook’s mind-control system, which it rents
767 out to anyone with a few bucks to spend.
768 </p><p>
769 To understand what role Facebook plays in the formulation and mobilization
770 of antisocial movements, we need to understand the dual nature of Facebook.
771 </p><p>
772 Because it has a lot of users and a lot of data about those users, Facebook
773 is a very efficient tool for locating people with hard-to-find traits, the
774 kinds of traits that are widely diffused in the population such that
775 advertisers have historically struggled to find a cost-effective way to
776 reach them. Think back to refrigerators: Most of us only replace our major
777 appliances a few times in our entire lives. If you’re a refrigerator
778 manufacturer or retailer, you have these brief windows in the life of a
779 consumer during which they are pondering a purchase, and you have to somehow
780 reach them. Anyone who’s ever registered a title change after buying a house
781 can attest that appliance manufacturers are incredibly desperate to reach
782 anyone who has even the slenderest chance of being in the market for a new
783 fridge.
784 </p><p>
785 Facebook makes finding people shopping for refrigerators a
786 <span class="emphasis"><em>lot</em></span> easier. It can target ads to people who’ve
787 registered a new home purchase, to people who’ve searched for refrigerator
788 buying advice, to people who have complained about their fridge dying, or
789 any combination thereof. It can even target people who’ve recently bought
790 <span class="emphasis"><em>other</em></span> kitchen appliances on the theory that someone
791 who’s just replaced their stove and dishwasher might be in a fridge-buying
792 kind of mood. The vast majority of people who are reached by these ads will
793 not be in the market for a new fridge, but — crucially — the percentage of
794 people who <span class="emphasis"><em>are</em></span> looking for fridges that these ads reach
795 is <span class="emphasis"><em>much</em></span> larger than it is than for any group that might
796 be subjected to traditional, offline targeted refrigerator marketing.
797 </p><p>
798 Facebook also makes it a lot easier to find people who have the same rare
799 disease as you, which might have been impossible in earlier eras — the
800 closest fellow sufferer might otherwise be hundreds of miles away. It makes
801 it easier to find people who went to the same high school as you even though
802 decades have passed and your former classmates have all been scattered to
803 the four corners of the Earth.
804 </p><p>
805 Facebook also makes it much easier to find people who hold the same rare
806 political beliefs as you. If you’ve always harbored a secret affinity for
807 socialism but never dared utter this aloud lest you be demonized by your
808 neighbors, Facebook can help you discover other people who feel the same way
809 (and it might just demonstrate to you that your affinity is more widespread
810 than you ever suspected). It can make it easier to find people who share
811 your sexual identity. And again, it can help you to understand that what
812 you thought was a shameful secret that affected only you was really a widely
813 shared trait, giving you both comfort and the courage to come out to the
814 people in your life.
815 </p><p>
816 All of this presents a dilemma for Facebook: Targeting makes the company’s
817 ads more effective than traditional ads, but it also lets advertisers see
818 just how effective their ads are. While advertisers are pleased to learn
819 that Facebook ads are more effective than ads on systems with less
820 sophisticated targeting, advertisers can also see that in nearly every case,
821 the people who see their ads ignore them. Or, at best, the ads work on a
822 subconscious level, creating nebulous unmeasurables like <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">brand
823 recognition.</span> »</span> This means that the price per ad is very low in nearly
824 every case.
825 </p><p>
826 To make things worse, many Facebook groups spark precious little
827 discussion. Your little-league soccer team, the people with the same rare
828 disease as you, and the people you share a political affinity with may
829 exchange the odd flurry of messages at critical junctures, but on a daily
830 basis, there’s not much to say to your old high school chums or other
831 hockey-card collectors.
832 </p><p>
833 With nothing but <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">organic</span> »</span> discussion, Facebook would not
834 generate enough traffic to sell enough ads to make the money it needs to
835 continually expand by buying up its competitors while returning handsome
836 sums to its investors.
837 </p><p>
838 So Facebook has to gin up traffic by sidetracking its own forums: Every time
839 Facebook’s algorithm injects controversial materials — inflammatory
840 political articles, conspiracy theories, outrage stories — into a group, it
841 can hijack that group’s nominal purpose with its desultory discussions and
842 supercharge those discussions by turning them into bitter, unproductive
843 arguments that drag on and on. Facebook is optimized for engagement, not
844 happiness, and it turns out that automated systems are pretty good at
845 figuring out things that people will get angry about.
846 </p><p>
847 Facebook <span class="emphasis"><em>can</em></span> modify our behavior but only in a couple
848 of trivial ways. First, it can lock in all your friends and family members
849 so that you check and check and check with Facebook to find out what they
850 are up to; and second, it can make you angry and anxious. It can force you
851 to choose between being interrupted constantly by updates — a process that
852 breaks your concentration and makes it hard to be introspective — and
853 staying in touch with your friends. This is a very limited form of mind
854 control, and it can only really make us miserable, angry, and anxious.
855 </p><p>
856 This is why Facebook’s targeting systems — both the ones it shows to
857 advertisers and the ones that let users find people who share their
858 interests — are so next-gen and smooth and easy to use as well as why its
859 message boards have a toolset that seems like it hasn’t changed since the
860 mid-2000s. If Facebook delivered an equally flexible, sophisticated
861 message-reading system to its users, those users could defend themselves
862 against being nonconsensually eyeball-fucked with Donald Trump headlines.
863 </p><p>
864 The more time you spend on Facebook, the more ads it gets to show you. The
865 solution to Facebook’s ads only working one in a thousand times is for the
866 company to try to increase how much time you spend on Facebook by a factor
867 of a thousand. Rather than thinking of Facebook as a company that has
868 figured out how to show you exactly the right ad in exactly the right way to
869 get you to do what its advertisers want, think of it as a company that has
870 figured out how to make you slog through an endless torrent of arguments
871 even though they make you miserable, spending so much time on the site that
872 it eventually shows you at least one ad that you respond to.
873 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="monopoly-and-the-right-to-the-future-tense"></a>Monopoly and the right to the future tense</h2></div></div></div><p>
874 Zuboff and her cohort are particularly alarmed at the extent to which
875 surveillance allows corporations to influence our decisions, taking away
876 something she poetically calls <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">the right to the future tense</span> »</span>
877 — that is, the right to decide for yourself what you will do in the future.
878 </p><p>
879 It’s true that advertising can tip the scales one way or another: When
880 you’re thinking of buying a fridge, a timely fridge ad might end the search
881 on the spot. But Zuboff puts enormous and undue weight on the persuasive
882 power of surveillance-based influence techniques. Most of these don’t work
883 very well, and the ones that do won’t work for very long. The makers of
884 these influence tools are confident they will someday refine them into
885 systems of total control, but they are hardly unbiased observers, and the
886 risks from their dreams coming true are very speculative.
887 </p><p>
888 By contrast, Zuboff is rather sanguine about 40 years of lax antitrust
889 practice that has allowed a handful of companies to dominate the internet,
890 ushering in an information age with, <a class="ulink" href="https://twitter.com/tveastman/status/1069674780826071040" target="_top">as one person
891 on Twitter noted</a>, five giant websites each filled with screenshots
892 of the other four.
893 </p><p>
894 However, if we are to be alarmed that we might lose the right to choose for
895 ourselves what our future will hold, then monopoly’s nonspeculative,
896 concrete, here-and-now harms should be front and center in our debate over
897 tech policy.
898 </p><p>
899 Start with <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">digital rights management.</span> »</span> In 1998, Bill Clinton
900 signed the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) into law. It’s a complex
901 piece of legislation with many controversial clauses but none more so than
902 Section 1201, the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">anti-circumvention</span> »</span> rule.
903 </p><p>
904 This is a blanket ban on tampering with systems that restrict access to
905 copyrighted works. The ban is so thoroughgoing that it prohibits removing a
906 copyright lock even when no copyright infringement takes place. This is by
907 design: The activities that the DMCA’s Section 1201 sets out to ban are not
908 copyright infringements; rather, they are legal activities that frustrate
909 manufacturers’ commercial plans.
910 </p><p>
911 For example, Section 1201’s first major application was on DVD players as a
912 means of enforcing the region coding built into those devices. DVD-CCA, the
913 body that standardized DVDs and DVD players, divided the world into six
914 regions and specified that DVD players must check each disc to determine
915 which regions it was authorized to be played in. DVD players would have
916 their own corresponding region (a DVD player bought in the U.S. would be
917 region 1 while one bought in India would be region 5). If the player and the
918 disc’s region matched, the player would play the disc; otherwise, it would
919 reject it.
920 </p><p>
921 However, watching a lawfully produced disc in a country other than the one
922 where you purchased it is not copyright infringement — it’s the
923 opposite. Copyright law imposes this duty on customers for a movie: You must
924 go into a store, find a licensed disc, and pay the asking price. Do that —
925 and <span class="emphasis"><em>nothing else</em></span> — and you and copyright are square
926 with one another.
927 </p><p>
928 The fact that a movie studio wants to charge Indians less than Americans or
929 release in Australia later than it releases in the U.K. has no bearing on
930 copyright law. Once you lawfully acquire a DVD, it is no copyright
931 infringement to watch it no matter where you happen to be.
932 </p><p>
933 So DVD and DVD player manufacturers would not be able to use accusations of
934 abetting copyright infringement to punish manufacturers who made
935 noncompliant players that would play discs from any region or repair shops
936 that modified players to let you watch out-of-region discs or software
937 programmers who created programs to let you do this.
938 </p><p>
939 That’s where Section 1201 of the DMCA comes in: By banning tampering with an
940 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">access control,</span> »</span> the rule gave manufacturers and rights
941 holders standing to sue competitors who released superior products with
942 lawful features that the market demanded (in this case, region-free
943 players).
944 </p><p>
945 This is an odious scam against consumers, but as time went by, Section 1201
946 grew to encompass a rapidly expanding constellation of devices and services
947 as canny manufacturers have realized certain things:
948 </p><div class="itemizedlist"><ul class="itemizedlist compact" style="list-style-type: disc; "><li class="listitem"><p>
949 Any device with software in it contains a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">copyrighted work</span> »</span>
950 i.e., the software.
951 </p></li><li class="listitem"><p>
952 A device can be designed so that reconfiguring the software requires
953 bypassing an <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">access control for copyrighted works,</span> »</span> which is a
954 potential felony under Section 1201.
955 </p></li><li class="listitem"><p>
956 Thus, companies can control their customers’ behavior after they take home
957 their purchases by designing products so that all unpermitted uses require
958 modifications that fall afoul of Section 1201.
959 </p></li></ul></div><p>
960 Section 1201 then becomes a means for manufacturers of all descriptions to
961 force their customers to arrange their affairs to benefit the manufacturers’
962 shareholders instead of themselves.
963 </p><p>
964 This manifests in many ways: from a new generation of inkjet printers that
965 use countermeasures to prevent third-party ink that cannot be bypassed
966 without legal risks to similar systems in tractors that prevent third-party
967 technicians from swapping in the manufacturer’s own parts that are not
968 recognized by the tractor’s control system until it is supplied with a
969 manufacturer’s unlock code.
970 </p><p>
971 Closer to home, Apple’s iPhones use these measures to prevent both
972 third-party service and third-party software installation. This allows Apple
973 to decide when an iPhone is beyond repair and must be shredded and
974 landfilled as opposed to the iPhone’s purchaser. (Apple is notorious for its
975 environmentally catastrophic policy of destroying old electronics rather
976 than permitting them to be cannibalized for parts.) This is a very useful
977 power to wield, especially in light of CEO Tim Cook’s January 2019 warning
978 to investors that the company’s profits are endangered by customers choosing
979 to hold onto their phones for longer rather than replacing them.
980 </p><p>
981 Apple’s use of copyright locks also allows it to establish a monopoly over
982 how its customers acquire software for their mobile devices. The App Store’s
983 commercial terms guarantee Apple a share of all revenues generated by the
984 apps sold there, meaning that Apple gets paid when you buy an app from its
985 store and then continues to get paid every time you buy something using that
986 app. This comes out of the bottom line of software developers, who must
987 either charge more or accept lower profits for their products.
988 </p><p>
989 Crucially, Apple’s use of copyright locks gives it the power to make
990 editorial decisions about which apps you may and may not install on your own
991 device. Apple has used this power to <a class="ulink" href="https://www.telegraph.co.uk/technology/apple/5982243/Apple-bans-dictionary-from-App-Store-over-swear-words.html" target="_top">reject
992 dictionaries</a> for containing obscene words; to <a class="ulink" href="https://www.vice.com/en_us/article/538kan/apple-just-banned-the-app-that-tracks-us-drone-strikes-again" target="_top">limit
993 political speech</a>, especially from apps that make sensitive political
994 commentary such as an app that notifies you every time a U.S. drone kills
995 someone somewhere in the world; and to <a class="ulink" href="https://www.eurogamer.net/articles/2016-05-19-palestinian-indie-game-must-not-be-called-a-game-apple-says" target="_top">object
996 to a game</a> that commented on the Israel-Palestine conflict.
997 </p><p>
998 Apple often justifies monopoly power over software installation in the name
999 of security, arguing that its vetting of apps for its store means that it
1000 can guard its users against apps that contain surveillance code. But this
1001 cuts both ways. In China, the government <a class="ulink" href="https://www.ft.com/content/ad42e536-cf36-11e7-b781-794ce08b24dc" target="_top">ordered
1002 Apple to prohibit the sale of privacy tools</a> like VPNs with the
1003 exception of VPNs that had deliberately introduced flaws designed to let the
1004 Chinese state eavesdrop on users. Because Apple uses technological
1005 countermeasures — with legal backstops — to block customers from installing
1006 unauthorized apps, Chinese iPhone owners cannot readily (or legally) acquire
1007 VPNs that would protect them from Chinese state snooping.
1008 </p><p>
1009 Zuboff calls surveillance capitalism a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism.</span> »</span>
1010 Theoreticians of capitalism claim that its virtue is that it <a class="ulink" href="https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_signal" target="_top">aggregates information in
1011 the form of consumers’ decisions</a>, producing efficient
1012 markets. Surveillance capitalism’s supposed power to rob its victims of
1013 their free will through computationally supercharged influence campaigns
1014 means that our markets no longer aggregate customers’ decisions because we
1015 customers no longer decide — we are given orders by surveillance
1016 capitalism’s mind-control rays.
1017 </p><p>
1018 If our concern is that markets cease to function when consumers can no
1019 longer make choices, then copyright locks should concern us at
1020 <span class="emphasis"><em>least</em></span> as much as influence campaigns. An influence
1021 campaign might nudge you to buy a certain brand of phone; but the copyright
1022 locks on that phone absolutely determine where you get it serviced, which
1023 apps can run on it, and when you have to throw it away rather than fixing
1024 it.
1025 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="search-order-and-the-right-to-the-future-tense"></a>Search order and the right to the future tense</h2></div></div></div><p>
1026 Markets are posed as a kind of magic: By discovering otherwise hidden
1027 information conveyed by the free choices of consumers, those consumers’
1028 local knowledge is integrated into a self-correcting system that makes
1029 efficient allocations—more efficient than any computer could calculate. But
1030 monopolies are incompatible with that notion. When you only have one app
1031 store, the owner of the store — not the consumer — decides on the range of
1032 choices. As Boss Tweed once said, <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">I don’t care who does the electing,
1033 so long as I get to do the nominating.</span> »</span> A monopolized market is an
1034 election whose candidates are chosen by the monopolist.
1035 </p><p>
1036 This ballot rigging is made more pernicious by the existence of monopolies
1037 over search order. Google’s search market share is about 90%. When Google’s
1038 ranking algorithm puts a result for a popular search term in its top 10,
1039 that helps determine the behavior of millions of people. If Google’s answer
1040 to <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Are vaccines dangerous?</span> »</span> is a page that rebuts anti-vax
1041 conspiracy theories, then a sizable portion of the public will learn that
1042 vaccines are safe. If, on the other hand, Google sends those people to a
1043 site affirming the anti-vax conspiracies, a sizable portion of those
1044 millions will come away convinced that vaccines are dangerous.
1045 </p><p>
1046 Google’s algorithm is often tricked into serving disinformation as a
1047 prominent search result. But in these cases, Google isn’t persuading people
1048 to change their minds; it’s just presenting something untrue as fact when
1049 the user has no cause to doubt it.
1050 </p><p>
1051 This is true whether the search is for <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Are vaccines
1052 dangerous?</span> »</span> or <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">best restaurants near me.</span> »</span> Most users
1053 will never look past the first page of search results, and when the
1054 overwhelming majority of people all use the same search engine, the ranking
1055 algorithm deployed by that search engine will determine myriad outcomes
1056 (whether to adopt a child, whether to have cancer surgery, where to eat
1057 dinner, where to move, where to apply for a job) to a degree that vastly
1058 outstrips any behavioral outcomes dictated by algorithmic persuasion
1059 techniques.
1060 </p><p>
1061 Many of the questions we ask search engines have no empirically correct
1062 answers: <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Where should I eat dinner?</span> »</span> is not an objective
1063 question. Even questions that do have correct answers (<span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Are vaccines
1064 dangerous?</span> »</span>) don’t have one empirically superior source for that
1065 answer. Many pages affirm the safety of vaccines, so which one goes first?
1066 Under conditions of competition, consumers can choose from many search
1067 engines and stick with the one whose algorithmic judgment suits them best,
1068 but under conditions of monopoly, we all get our answers from the same
1069 place.
1070 </p><p>
1071 Google’s search dominance isn’t a matter of pure merit: The company has
1072 leveraged many tactics that would have been prohibited under classical,
1073 pre-Ronald-Reagan antitrust enforcement standards to attain its
1074 dominance. After all, this is a company that has developed two major
1075 products: a really good search engine and a pretty good Hotmail clone. Every
1076 other major success it’s had — Android, YouTube, Google Maps, etc. — has
1077 come through an acquisition of a nascent competitor. Many of the company’s
1078 key divisions, such as the advertising technology of DoubleClick, violate
1079 the historical antitrust principle of structural separation, which forbade
1080 firms from owning subsidiaries that competed with their
1081 customers. Railroads, for example, were barred from owning freight companies
1082 that competed with the shippers whose freight they carried.
1083 </p><p>
1084 If we’re worried about giant companies subverting markets by stripping
1085 consumers of their ability to make free choices, then vigorous antitrust
1086 enforcement seems like an excellent remedy. If we’d denied Google the right
1087 to effect its many mergers, we would also have probably denied it its total
1088 search dominance. Without that dominance, the pet theories, biases, errors
1089 (and good judgment, too) of Google search engineers and product managers
1090 would not have such an outsized effect on consumer choice.
1091 </p><p>
1092 This goes for many other companies. Amazon, a classic surveillance
1093 capitalist, is obviously the dominant tool for searching Amazon — though
1094 many people find their way to Amazon through Google searches and Facebook
1095 posts — and obviously, Amazon controls Amazon search. That means that
1096 Amazon’s own self-serving editorial choices—like promoting its own house
1097 brands over rival goods from its sellers as well as its own pet theories,
1098 biases, and errors— determine much of what we buy on Amazon. And since
1099 Amazon is the dominant e-commerce retailer outside of China and since it
1100 attained that dominance by buying up both large rivals and nascent
1101 competitors in defiance of historical antitrust rules, we can blame the
1102 monopoly for stripping consumers of their right to the future tense and the
1103 ability to shape markets by making informed choices.
1104 </p><p>
1105 Not every monopolist is a surveillance capitalist, but that doesn’t mean
1106 they’re not able to shape consumer choices in wide-ranging ways. Zuboff
1107 lauds Apple for its App Store and iTunes Store, insisting that adding price
1108 tags to the features on its platforms has been the secret to resisting
1109 surveillance and thus creating markets. But Apple is the only retailer
1110 allowed to sell on its platforms, and it’s the second-largest mobile device
1111 vendor in the world. The independent software vendors that sell through
1112 Apple’s marketplace accuse the company of the same surveillance sins as
1113 Amazon and other big retailers: spying on its customers to find lucrative
1114 new products to launch, effectively using independent software vendors as
1115 free-market researchers, then forcing them out of any markets they discover.
1116 </p><p>
1117 Because of its use of copyright locks, Apple’s mobile customers are not
1118 legally allowed to switch to a rival retailer for its apps if they want to
1119 do so on an iPhone. Apple, obviously, is the only entity that gets to decide
1120 how it ranks the results of search queries in its stores. These decisions
1121 ensure that some apps are often installed (because they appear on page one)
1122 and others are never installed (because they appear on page one
1123 million). Apple’s search-ranking design decisions have a vastly more
1124 significant effect on consumer behaviors than influence campaigns delivered
1125 by surveillance capitalism’s ad-serving bots.
1126 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="monopolists-can-afford-sleeping-pills-for-watchdogs"></a>Monopolists can afford sleeping pills for watchdogs</h2></div></div></div><p>
1127 Only the most extreme market ideologues think that markets can self-regulate
1128 without state oversight. Markets need watchdogs — regulators, lawmakers, and
1129 other elements of democratic control — to keep them honest. When these
1130 watchdogs sleep on the job, then markets cease to aggregate consumer choices
1131 because those choices are constrained by illegitimate and deceptive
1132 activities that companies are able to get away with because no one is
1133 holding them to account.
1134 </p><p>
1135 But this kind of regulatory capture doesn’t come cheap. In competitive
1136 sectors, where rivals are constantly eroding one another’s margins,
1137 individual firms lack the surplus capital to effectively lobby for laws and
1138 regulations that serve their ends.
1139 </p><p>
1140 Many of the harms of surveillance capitalism are the result of weak or
1141 nonexistent regulation. Those regulatory vacuums spring from the power of
1142 monopolists to resist stronger regulation and to tailor what regulation
1143 exists to permit their existing businesses.
1144 </p><p>
1145 Here’s an example: When firms over-collect and over-retain our data, they
1146 are at increased risk of suffering a breach — you can’t leak data you never
1147 collected, and once you delete all copies of that data, you can no longer
1148 leak it. For more than a decade, we’ve lived through an endless parade of
1149 ever-worsening data breaches, each one uniquely horrible in the scale of
1150 data breached and the sensitivity of that data.
1151 </p><p>
1152 But still, firms continue to over-collect and over-retain our data for three
1153 reasons:
1154 </p><p>
1155 <span class="strong"><strong>1. They are locked in the aforementioned limbic arms
1156 race with our capacity to shore up our attentional defense systems to resist
1157 their new persuasion techniques.</strong></span> They’re also locked in an arms
1158 race with their competitors to find new ways to target people for sales
1159 pitches. As soon as they discover a soft spot in our attentional defenses (a
1160 counterintuitive, unobvious way to target potential refrigerator buyers),
1161 the public begins to wise up to the tactic, and their competitors leap on
1162 it, hastening the day in which all potential refrigerator buyers have been
1163 inured to the pitch.
1164 </p><p>
1165 <span class="strong"><strong>2. They believe the surveillance capitalism
1166 story.</strong></span> Data is cheap to aggregate and store, and both proponents
1167 and opponents of surveillance capitalism have assured managers and product
1168 designers that if you collect enough data, you will be able to perform
1169 sorcerous acts of mind control, thus supercharging your sales. Even if you
1170 never figure out how to profit from the data, someone else will eventually
1171 offer to buy it from you to give it a try. This is the hallmark of all
1172 economic bubbles: acquiring an asset on the assumption that someone else
1173 will buy it from you for more than you paid for it, often to sell to someone
1174 else at an even greater price.
1175 </p><p>
1176 <span class="strong"><strong>3. The penalties for leaking data are
1177 negligible.</strong></span> Most countries limit these penalties to actual
1178 damages, meaning that consumers who’ve had their data breached have to show
1179 actual monetary harms to get a reward. In 2014, Home Depot disclosed that it
1180 had lost credit-card data for 53 million of its customers, but it settled
1181 the matter by paying those customers about $0.34 each — and a third of that
1182 $0.34 wasn’t even paid in cash. It took the form of a credit to procure a
1183 largely ineffectual credit-monitoring service.
1184 </p><p>
1185 But the harms from breaches are much more extensive than these
1186 actual-damages rules capture. Identity thieves and fraudsters are wily and
1187 endlessly inventive. All the vast breaches of our century are being
1188 continuously recombined, the data sets merged and mined for new ways to
1189 victimize the people whose data was present in them. Any reasonable,
1190 evidence-based theory of deterrence and compensation for breaches would not
1191 confine damages to actual damages but rather would allow users to claim
1192 these future harms.
1193 </p><p>
1194 However, even the most ambitious privacy rules, such as the EU General Data
1195 Protection Regulation, fall far short of capturing the negative
1196 externalities of the platforms’ negligent over-collection and
1197 over-retention, and what penalties they do provide are not aggressively
1198 pursued by regulators.
1199 </p><p>
1200 This tolerance of — or indifference to — data over-collection and
1201 over-retention can be ascribed in part to the sheer lobbying muscle of the
1202 platforms. They are so profitable that they can handily afford to divert
1203 gigantic sums to fight any real change — that is, change that would force
1204 them to internalize the costs of their surveillance activities.
1205 </p><p>
1206 And then there’s state surveillance, which the surveillance capitalism story
1207 dismisses as a relic of another era when the big worry was being jailed for
1208 your dissident speech, not having your free will stripped away with machine
1209 learning.
1210 </p><p>
1211 But state surveillance and private surveillance are intimately related. As
1212 we saw when Apple was conscripted by the Chinese government as a vital
1213 collaborator in state surveillance, the only really affordable and tractable
1214 way to conduct mass surveillance on the scale practiced by modern states —
1215 both <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">free</span> »</span> and autocratic states — is to suborn commercial
1216 services.
1217 </p><p>
1218 Whether it’s Google being used as a location tracking tool by local law
1219 enforcement across the U.S. or the use of social media tracking by the
1220 Department of Homeland Security to build dossiers on participants in
1221 protests against Immigration and Customs Enforcement’s family separation
1222 practices, any hard limits on surveillance capitalism would hamstring the
1223 state’s own surveillance capability. Without Palantir, Amazon, Google, and
1224 other major tech contractors, U.S. cops would not be able to spy on Black
1225 people, ICE would not be able to manage the caging of children at the U.S.
1226 border, and state welfare systems would not be able to purge their rolls by
1227 dressing up cruelty as empiricism and claiming that poor and vulnerable
1228 people are ineligible for assistance. At least some of the states’
1229 unwillingness to take meaningful action to curb surveillance should be
1230 attributed to this symbiotic relationship. There is no mass state
1231 surveillance without mass commercial surveillance.
1232 </p><p>
1233 Monopolism is key to the project of mass state surveillance. It’s true that
1234 smaller tech firms are apt to be less well-defended than Big Tech, whose
1235 security experts are drawn from the tops of their field and who are given
1236 enormous resources to secure and monitor their systems against
1237 intruders. But smaller firms also have less to protect: fewer users whose
1238 data is more fragmented across more systems and have to be suborned one at a
1239 time by state actors.
1240 </p><p>
1241 A concentrated tech sector that works with authorities is a much more
1242 powerful ally in the project of mass state surveillance than a fragmented
1243 one composed of smaller actors. The U.S. tech sector is small enough that
1244 all of its top executives fit around a single boardroom table in Trump Tower
1245 in 2017, shortly after Trump’s inauguration. Most of its biggest players bid
1246 to win JEDI, the Pentagon’s $10 billion Joint Enterprise Defense
1247 Infrastructure cloud contract. Like other highly concentrated industries,
1248 Big Tech rotates its key employees in and out of government service, sending
1249 them to serve in the Department of Defense and the White House, then hiring
1250 ex-Pentagon and ex-DOD top staffers and officers to work in their own
1251 government relations departments.
1252 </p><p>
1253 They can even make a good case for doing this: After all, when there are
1254 only four or five big companies in an industry, everyone qualified to
1255 regulate those companies has served as an executive in at least a couple of
1256 them — because, likewise, when there are only five companies in an industry,
1257 everyone qualified for a senior role at any of them is by definition working
1258 at one of the other ones.
1259 </p><div class="blockquote"><blockquote class="blockquote"><p>
1260 While surveillance doesn’t cause monopolies, monopolies certainly abet
1261 surveillance.
1262 </p></blockquote></div><p>
1263 Industries that are competitive are fragmented — composed of companies that
1264 are at each other’s throats all the time and eroding one another’s margins
1265 in bids to steal their best customers. This leaves them with much more
1266 limited capital to use to lobby for favorable rules and a much harder job of
1267 getting everyone to agree to pool their resources to benefit the industry as
1268 a whole.
1269 </p><p>
1270 Surveillance combined with machine learning is supposed to be an existential
1271 crisis, a species-defining moment at which our free will is just a few more
1272 advances in the field from being stripped away. I am skeptical of this
1273 claim, but I <span class="emphasis"><em>do</em></span> think that tech poses an existential
1274 threat to our society and possibly our species.
1275 </p><p>
1276 But that threat grows out of monopoly.
1277 </p><p>
1278 One of the consequences of tech’s regulatory capture is that it can shift
1279 liability for poor security decisions onto its customers and the wider
1280 society. It is absolutely normal in tech for companies to obfuscate the
1281 workings of their products, to make them deliberately hard to understand,
1282 and to threaten security researchers who seek to independently audit those
1283 products.
1284 </p><p>
1285 IT is the only field in which this is practiced: No one builds a bridge or a
1286 hospital and keeps the composition of the steel or the equations used to
1287 calculate load stresses a secret. It is a frankly bizarre practice that
1288 leads, time and again, to grotesque security defects on farcical scales,
1289 with whole classes of devices being revealed as vulnerable long after they
1290 are deployed in the field and put into sensitive places.
1291 </p><p>
1292 The monopoly power that keeps any meaningful consequences for breaches at
1293 bay means that tech companies continue to build terrible products that are
1294 insecure by design and that end up integrated into our lives, in possession
1295 of our data, and connected to our physical world. For years, Boeing has
1296 struggled with the aftermath of a series of bad technology decisions that
1297 made its 737 fleet a global pariah, a rare instance in which bad tech
1298 decisions have been seriously punished in the market.
1299 </p><p>
1300 These bad security decisions are compounded yet again by the use of
1301 copyright locks to enforce business-model decisions against
1302 consumers. Recall that these locks have become the go-to means for shaping
1303 consumer behavior, making it technically impossible to use third-party ink,
1304 insulin, apps, or service depots in connection with your lawfully acquired
1305 property.
1306 </p><p>
1307 Recall also that these copyright locks are backstopped by legislation (such
1308 as Section 1201 of the DMCA or Article 6 of the 2001 EU Copyright Directive)
1309 that ban tampering with (<span class="quote">« <span class="quote">circumventing</span> »</span>) them, and these
1310 statutes have been used to threaten security researchers who make
1311 disclosures about vulnerabilities without permission from manufacturers.
1312 </p><p>
1313 This amounts to a manufacturer’s veto over safety warnings and
1314 criticism. While this is far from the legislative intent of the DMCA and its
1315 sister statutes around the world, Congress has not intervened to clarify the
1316 statute nor will it because to do so would run counter to the interests of
1317 powerful, large firms whose lobbying muscle is unstoppable.
1318 </p><p>
1319 Copyright locks are a double whammy: They create bad security decisions that
1320 can’t be freely investigated or discussed. If markets are supposed to be
1321 machines for aggregating information (and if surveillance capitalism’s
1322 notional mind-control rays are what make it a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue
1323 capitalism</span> »</span> because it denies consumers the power to make decisions),
1324 then a program of legally enforced ignorance of the risks of products makes
1325 monopolism even more of a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism</span> »</span> than surveillance
1326 capitalism’s influence campaigns.
1327 </p><p>
1328 And unlike mind-control rays, enforced silence over security is an
1329 immediate, documented problem, and it <span class="emphasis"><em>does</em></span> constitute
1330 an existential threat to our civilization and possibly our species. The
1331 proliferation of insecure devices — especially devices that spy on us and
1332 especially when those devices also can manipulate the physical world by,
1333 say, steering your car or flipping a breaker at a power station — is a kind
1334 of technology debt.
1335 </p><p>
1336 In software design, <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">technology debt</span> »</span> refers to old, baked-in
1337 decisions that turn out to be bad ones in hindsight. Perhaps a long-ago
1338 developer decided to incorporate a networking protocol made by a vendor that
1339 has since stopped supporting it. But everything in the product still relies
1340 on that superannuated protocol, and so, with each revision, the product team
1341 has to work around this obsolete core, adding compatibility layers,
1342 surrounding it with security checks that try to shore up its defenses, and
1343 so on. These Band-Aid measures compound the debt because every subsequent
1344 revision has to make allowances for <span class="emphasis"><em>them</em></span>, too, like
1345 interest mounting on a predatory subprime loan. And like a subprime loan,
1346 the interest mounts faster than you can hope to pay it off: The product team
1347 has to put so much energy into maintaining this complex, brittle system that
1348 they don’t have any time left over to refactor the product from the ground
1349 up and <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">pay off the debt</span> »</span> once and for all.
1350 </p><p>
1351 Typically, technology debt results in a technological bankruptcy: The
1352 product gets so brittle and unsustainable that it fails
1353 catastrophically. Think of the antiquated COBOL-based banking and accounting
1354 systems that fell over at the start of the pandemic emergency when
1355 confronted with surges of unemployment claims. Sometimes that ends the
1356 product; sometimes it takes the company down with it. Being caught in the
1357 default of a technology debt is scary and traumatic, just like losing your
1358 house due to bankruptcy is scary and traumatic.
1359 </p><p>
1360 But the technology debt created by copyright locks isn’t individual debt;
1361 it’s systemic. Everyone in the world is exposed to this over-leverage, as
1362 was the case with the 2008 financial crisis. When that debt comes due — when
1363 we face a cascade of security breaches that threaten global shipping and
1364 logistics, the food supply, pharmaceutical production pipelines, emergency
1365 communications, and other critical systems that are accumulating technology
1366 debt in part due to the presence of deliberately insecure and deliberately
1367 unauditable copyright locks — it will indeed pose an existential risk.
1368 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="privacy-and-monopoly"></a>Privacy and monopoly</h2></div></div></div><p>
1369 Many tech companies are gripped by an orthodoxy that holds that if they just
1370 gather enough data on enough of our activities, everything else is possible
1371 — the mind control and endless profits. This is an unfalsifiable hypothesis:
1372 If data gives a tech company even a tiny improvement in behavior prediction
1373 and modification, the company declares that it has taken the first step
1374 toward global domination with no end in sight. If a company
1375 <span class="emphasis"><em>fails</em></span> to attain any improvements from gathering and
1376 analyzing data, it declares success to be just around the corner, attainable
1377 once more data is in hand.
1378 </p><p>
1379 Surveillance tech is far from the first industry to embrace a nonsensical,
1380 self-serving belief that harms the rest of the world, and it is not the
1381 first industry to profit handsomely from such a delusion. Long before
1382 hedge-fund managers were claiming (falsely) that they could beat the
1383 S&amp;P 500, there were plenty of other <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">respectable</span> »</span>
1384 industries that have been revealed as quacks in hindsight. From the makers
1385 of radium suppositories (a real thing!) to the cruel sociopaths who claimed
1386 they could <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">cure</span> »</span> gay people, history is littered with the
1387 formerly respectable titans of discredited industries.
1388 </p><p>
1389 This is not to say that there’s nothing wrong with Big Tech and its
1390 ideological addiction to data. While surveillance’s benefits are mostly
1391 overstated, its harms are, if anything, <span class="emphasis"><em>understated</em></span>.
1392 </p><p>
1393 There’s real irony here. The belief in surveillance capitalism as a
1394 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism</span> »</span> is driven by the belief that markets
1395 wouldn’t tolerate firms that are gripped by false beliefs. An oil company
1396 that has false beliefs about where the oil is will eventually go broke
1397 digging dry wells after all.
1398 </p><p>
1399 But monopolists get to do terrible things for a long time before they pay
1400 the price. Think of how concentration in the finance sector allowed the
1401 subprime crisis to fester as bond-rating agencies, regulators, investors,
1402 and critics all fell under the sway of a false belief that complex
1403 mathematics could construct <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">fully hedged</span> »</span> debt instruments
1404 that could not possibly default. A small bank that engaged in this kind of
1405 malfeasance would simply go broke rather than outrunning the inevitable
1406 crisis, perhaps growing so big that it averted it altogether. But large
1407 banks were able to continue to attract investors, and when they finally
1408 <span class="emphasis"><em>did</em></span> come a-cropper, the world’s governments bailed them
1409 out. The worst offenders of the subprime crisis are bigger than they were in
1410 2008, bringing home more profits and paying their execs even larger sums.
1411 </p><p>
1412 Big Tech is able to practice surveillance not just because it is tech but
1413 because it is <span class="emphasis"><em>big</em></span>. The reason every web publisher
1414 embeds a Facebook <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Like</span> »</span> button is that Facebook dominates the
1415 internet’s social media referrals — and every one of those
1416 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Like</span> »</span> buttons spies on everyone who lands on a page that
1417 contains them (see also: Google Analytics embeds, Twitter buttons, etc.).
1418 </p><p>
1419 The reason the world’s governments have been slow to create meaningful
1420 penalties for privacy breaches is that Big Tech’s concentration produces
1421 huge profits that can be used to lobby against those penalties — and Big
1422 Tech’s concentration means that the companies involved are able to arrive at
1423 a unified negotiating position that supercharges the lobbying.
1424 </p><p>
1425 The reason that the smartest engineers in the world want to work for Big
1426 Tech is that Big Tech commands the lion’s share of tech industry jobs.
1427 </p><p>
1428 The reason people who are aghast at Facebook’s and Google’s and Amazon’s
1429 data-handling practices continue to use these services is that all their
1430 friends are on Facebook; Google dominates search; and Amazon has put all the
1431 local merchants out of business.
1432 </p><p>
1433 Competitive markets would weaken the companies’ lobbying muscle by reducing
1434 their profits and pitting them against each other in regulatory forums. It
1435 would give customers other places to go to get their online services. It
1436 would make the companies small enough to regulate and pave the way to
1437 meaningful penalties for breaches. It would let engineers with ideas that
1438 challenged the surveillance orthodoxy raise capital to compete with the
1439 incumbents. It would give web publishers multiple ways to reach audiences
1440 and make the case against Facebook and Google and Twitter embeds.
1441 </p><p>
1442 In other words, while surveillance doesn’t cause monopolies, monopolies
1443 certainly abet surveillance.
1444 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="ronald-reagan-pioneer-of-tech-monopolism"></a>Ronald Reagan, pioneer of tech monopolism</h2></div></div></div><p>
1445 Technology exceptionalism is a sin, whether it’s practiced by technology’s
1446 blind proponents or by its critics. Both of these camps are prone to
1447 explaining away monopolistic concentration by citing some special
1448 characteristic of the tech industry, like network effects or first-mover
1449 advantage. The only real difference between these two groups is that the
1450 tech apologists say monopoly is inevitable so we should just let tech get
1451 away with its abuses while competition regulators in the U.S. and the EU say
1452 monopoly is inevitable so we should punish tech for its abuses but not try
1453 to break up the monopolies.
1454 </p><p>
1455 To understand how tech became so monopolistic, it’s useful to look at the
1456 dawn of the consumer tech industry: 1979, the year the Apple II Plus
1457 launched and became the first successful home computer. That also happens to
1458 be the year that Ronald Reagan hit the campaign trail for the 1980
1459 presidential race — a race he won, leading to a radical shift in the way
1460 that antitrust concerns are handled in America. Reagan’s cohort of
1461 politicians — including Margaret Thatcher in the U.K., Brian Mulroney in
1462 Canada, Helmut Kohl in Germany, and Augusto Pinochet in Chile — went on to
1463 enact similar reforms that eventually spread around the world.
1464 </p><p>
1465 Antitrust’s story began nearly a century before all that with laws like the
1466 Sherman Act, which took aim at monopolists on the grounds that monopolies
1467 were bad in and of themselves — squeezing out competitors, creating
1468 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">diseconomies of scale</span> »</span> (when a company is so big that its
1469 constituent parts go awry and it is seemingly helpless to address the
1470 problems), and capturing their regulators to such a degree that they can get
1471 away with a host of evils.
1472 </p><p>
1473 Then came a fabulist named Robert Bork, a former solicitor general who
1474 Reagan appointed to the powerful U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit
1475 and who had created an alternate legislative history of the Sherman Act and
1476 its successors out of whole cloth. Bork insisted that these statutes were
1477 never targeted at monopolies (despite a wealth of evidence to the contrary,
1478 including the transcribed speeches of the acts’ authors) but, rather, that
1479 they were intended to prevent <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">consumer harm</span> »</span> — in the form of
1480 higher prices.
1481 </p><p>
1482 Bork was a crank, but he was a crank with a theory that rich people really
1483 liked. Monopolies are a great way to make rich people richer by allowing
1484 them to receive <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">monopoly rents</span> »</span> (that is, bigger profits) and
1485 capture regulators, leading to a weaker, more favorable regulatory
1486 environment with fewer protections for customers, suppliers, the
1487 environment, and workers.
1488 </p><p>
1489 Bork’s theories were especially palatable to the same power brokers who
1490 backed Reagan, and Reagan’s Department of Justice and other agencies began
1491 to incorporate Bork’s antitrust doctrine into their enforcement decisions
1492 (Reagan even put Bork up for a Supreme Court seat, but Bork flunked the
1493 Senate confirmation hearing so badly that, 40 years later, D.C. insiders use
1494 the term <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">borked</span> »</span> to refer to any catastrophically bad
1495 political performance).
1496 </p><p>
1497 Little by little, Bork’s theories entered the mainstream, and their backers
1498 began to infiltrate the legal education field, even putting on junkets where
1499 members of the judiciary were treated to lavish meals, fun outdoor
1500 activities, and seminars where they were indoctrinated into the consumer
1501 harm theory of antitrust. The more Bork’s theories took hold, the more money
1502 the monopolists were making — and the more surplus capital they had at their
1503 disposal to lobby for even more Borkian antitrust influence campaigns.
1504 </p><p>
1505 The history of Bork’s antitrust theories is a really good example of the
1506 kind of covertly engineered shifts in public opinion that Zuboff warns us
1507 against, where fringe ideas become mainstream orthodoxy. But Bork didn’t
1508 change the world overnight. He played a very long game, for over a
1509 generation, and he had a tailwind because the same forces that backed
1510 oligarchic antitrust theories also backed many other oligarchic shifts in
1511 public opinion. For example, the idea that taxation is theft, that wealth is
1512 a sign of virtue, and so on — all of these theories meshed to form a
1513 coherent ideology that elevated inequality to a virtue.
1514 </p><p>
1515 Today, many fear that machine learning allows surveillance capitalism to
1516 sell <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Bork-as-a-Service,</span> »</span> at internet speeds, so that you can
1517 contract a machine-learning company to engineer <span class="emphasis"><em>rapid</em></span>
1518 shifts in public sentiment without needing the capital to sustain a
1519 multipronged, multigenerational project working at the local, state,
1520 national, and global levels in business, law, and philosophy. I do not
1521 believe that such a project is plausible, though I agree that this is
1522 basically what the platforms claim to be selling. They’re just lying about
1523 it. Big Tech lies all the time, <span class="emphasis"><em>including</em></span> in their
1524 sales literature.
1525 </p><p>
1526 The idea that tech forms <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">natural monopolies</span> »</span> (monopolies that
1527 are the inevitable result of the realities of an industry, such as the
1528 monopolies that accrue the first company to run long-haul phone lines or
1529 rail lines) is belied by tech’s own history: In the absence of
1530 anti-competitive tactics, Google was able to unseat AltaVista and Yahoo;
1531 Facebook was able to head off Myspace. There are some advantages to
1532 gathering mountains of data, but those mountains of data also have
1533 disadvantages: liability (from leaking), diminishing returns (from old
1534 data), and institutional inertia (big companies, like science, progress one
1535 funeral at a time).
1536 </p><p>
1537 Indeed, the birth of the web saw a mass-extinction event for the existing
1538 giant, wildly profitable proprietary technologies that had capital, network
1539 effects, and walls and moats surrounding their businesses. The web showed
1540 that when a new industry is built around a protocol, rather than a product,
1541 the combined might of everyone who uses the protocol to reach their
1542 customers or users or communities outweighs even the most massive
1543 products. CompuServe, AOL, MSN, and a host of other proprietary walled
1544 gardens learned this lesson the hard way: Each believed it could stay
1545 separate from the web, offering <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">curation</span> »</span> and a guarantee of
1546 consistency and quality instead of the chaos of an open system. Each was
1547 wrong and ended up being absorbed into the public web.
1548 </p><p>
1549 Yes, tech is heavily monopolized and is now closely associated with industry
1550 concentration, but this has more to do with a matter of timing than its
1551 intrinsically monopolistic tendencies. Tech was born at the moment that
1552 antitrust enforcement was being dismantled, and tech fell into exactly the
1553 same pathologies that antitrust was supposed to guard against. To a first
1554 approximation, it is reasonable to assume that tech’s monopolies are the
1555 result of a lack of anti-monopoly action and not the much-touted unique
1556 characteristics of tech, such as network effects, first-mover advantage, and
1557 so on.
1558 </p><p>
1559 In support of this thesis, I offer the concentration that every
1560 <span class="emphasis"><em>other</em></span> industry has undergone over the same period. From
1561 professional wrestling to consumer packaged goods to commercial property
1562 leasing to banking to sea freight to oil to record labels to newspaper
1563 ownership to theme parks, <span class="emphasis"><em>every</em></span> industry has undergone
1564 a massive shift toward concentration. There’s no obvious network effects or
1565 first-mover advantage at play in these industries. However, in every case,
1566 these industries attained their concentrated status through tactics that
1567 were prohibited before Bork’s triumph: merging with major competitors,
1568 buying out innovative new market entrants, horizontal and vertical
1569 integration, and a suite of anti-competitive tactics that were once illegal
1570 but are not any longer.
1571 </p><p>
1572 Again: When you change the laws intended to prevent monopolies and then
1573 monopolies form in exactly the way the law was supposed to prevent, it is
1574 reasonable to suppose that these facts are related. Tech’s concentration
1575 can be readily explained without recourse to radical theories of network
1576 effects — but only if you’re willing to indict unregulated markets as
1577 tending toward monopoly. Just as a lifelong smoker can give you a hundred
1578 reasons why their smoking didn’t cause their cancer (<span class="quote">« <span class="quote">It was the
1579 environmental toxins</span> »</span>), true believers in unregulated markets have a
1580 whole suite of unconvincing explanations for monopoly in tech that leave
1581 capitalism intact.
1582 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="steering-with-the-windshield-wipers"></a>Steering with the windshield wipers</h2></div></div></div><p>
1583 It’s been 40 years since Bork’s project to rehabilitate monopolies achieved
1584 liftoff, and that is a generation and a half, which is plenty of time to
1585 take a common idea and make it seem outlandish and vice versa. Before the
1586 1940s, affluent Americans dressed their baby boys in pink while baby girls
1587 wore blue (a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">delicate and dainty</span> »</span> color). While gendered
1588 colors are obviously totally arbitrary, many still greet this news with
1589 amazement and find it hard to imagine a time when pink connoted masculinity.
1590 </p><p>
1591 After 40 years of studiously ignoring antitrust analysis and enforcement,
1592 it’s not surprising that we’ve all but forgotten that antitrust exists, that
1593 in living memory, growth through mergers and acquisitions were largely
1594 prohibited under law, that market-cornering strategies like vertical
1595 integration could land a company in court.
1596 </p><p>
1597 Antitrust is a market society’s steering wheel, the control of first resort
1598 to keep would-be masters of the universe in their lanes. But Bork and his
1599 cohort ripped out our steering wheel 40 years ago. The car is still
1600 barreling along, and so we’re yanking as hard as we can on all the
1601 <span class="emphasis"><em>other</em></span> controls in the car as well as desperately
1602 flapping the doors and rolling the windows up and down in the hopes that one
1603 of these other controls can be repurposed to let us choose where we’re
1604 heading before we careen off a cliff.
1605 </p><p>
1606 It’s like a 1960s science-fiction plot come to life: People stuck in a
1607 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">generation ship,</span> »</span> plying its way across the stars, a ship once
1608 piloted by their ancestors; and now, after a great cataclysm, the ship’s
1609 crew have forgotten that they’re in a ship at all and no longer remember
1610 where the control room is. Adrift, the ship is racing toward its extinction,
1611 and unless we can seize the controls and execute emergency course
1612 correction, we’re all headed for a fiery death in the heart of a sun.
1613 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="surveillance-still-matters"></a>Surveillance still matters</h2></div></div></div><p>
1614 None of this is to minimize the problems with surveillance. Surveillance
1615 matters, and Big Tech’s use of surveillance <span class="emphasis"><em>is</em></span> an
1616 existential risk to our species, but that’s not because surveillance and
1617 machine learning rob us of our free will.
1618 </p><p>
1619 Surveillance has become <span class="emphasis"><em>much</em></span> more efficient thanks to
1620 Big Tech. In 1989, the Stasi — the East German secret police — had the whole
1621 country under surveillance, a massive undertaking that recruited one out of
1622 every 60 people to serve as an informant or intelligence operative.
1623 </p><p>
1624 Today, we know that the NSA is spying on a significant fraction of the
1625 entire world’s population, and its ratio of surveillance operatives to the
1626 surveilled is more like 1:10,000 (that’s probably on the low side since it
1627 assumes that every American with top-secret clearance is working for the NSA
1628 on this project — we don’t know how many of those cleared people are
1629 involved in NSA spying, but it’s definitely not all of them).
1630 </p><p>
1631 How did the ratio of surveillable citizens expand from 1:60 to 1:10,000 in
1632 less than 30 years? It’s thanks to Big Tech. Our devices and services gather
1633 most of the data that the NSA mines for its surveillance project. We pay for
1634 these devices and the services they connect to, and then we painstakingly
1635 perform the data-entry tasks associated with logging facts about our lives,
1636 opinions, and preferences. This mass surveillance project has been largely
1637 useless for fighting terrorism: The NSA can <a class="ulink" href="https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/national-security/nsa-cites-case-as-success-of-phone-data-collection-program/2013/08/08/fc915e5a-feda-11e2-96a8-d3b921c0924a_story.html" target="_top">only
1638 point to a single minor success story</a> in which it used its data
1639 collection program to foil an attempt by a U.S. resident to wire a few
1640 thousand dollars to an overseas terror group. It’s ineffective for much the
1641 same reason that commercial surveillance projects are largely ineffective at
1642 targeting advertising: The people who want to commit acts of terror, like
1643 people who want to buy a refrigerator, are extremely rare. If you’re trying
1644 to detect a phenomenon whose base rate is one in a million with an
1645 instrument whose accuracy is only 99%, then every true positive will come at
1646 the cost of 9,999 false positives.
1647 </p><p>
1648 Let me explain that again: If one in a million people is a terrorist, then
1649 there will only be about one terrorist in a random sample of one million
1650 people. If your test for detecting terrorists is 99% accurate, it will
1651 identify 10,000 terrorists in your million-person sample (1% of one million
1652 is 10,000). For every true positive, you’ll get 9,999 false positives.
1653 </p><p>
1654 In reality, the accuracy of algorithmic terrorism detection falls far short
1655 of the 99% mark, as does refrigerator ad targeting. The difference is that
1656 being falsely accused of wanting to buy a fridge is a minor nuisance while
1657 being falsely accused of planning a terror attack can destroy your life and
1658 the lives of everyone you love.
1659 </p><p>
1660 Mass state surveillance is only feasible because of surveillance capitalism
1661 and its extremely low-yield ad-targeting systems, which require a constant
1662 feed of personal data to remain barely viable. Surveillance capitalism’s
1663 primary failure mode is mistargeted ads while mass state surveillance’s
1664 primary failure mode is grotesque human rights abuses, tending toward
1665 totalitarianism.
1666 </p><p>
1667 State surveillance is no mere parasite on Big Tech, sucking up its data and
1668 giving nothing in return. In truth, the two are symbiotes: Big Tech sucks up
1669 our data for spy agencies, and spy agencies ensure that governments don’t
1670 limit Big Tech’s activities so severely that it would no longer serve the
1671 spy agencies’ needs. There is no firm distinction between state surveillance
1672 and surveillance capitalism; they are dependent on one another.
1673 </p><p>
1674 To see this at work today, look no further than Amazon’s home surveillance
1675 device, the Ring doorbell, and its associated app, Neighbors. Ring — a
1676 product that Amazon acquired and did not develop in house — makes a
1677 camera-enabled doorbell that streams footage from your front door to your
1678 mobile device. The Neighbors app allows you to form a neighborhood-wide
1679 surveillance grid with your fellow Ring owners through which you can share
1680 clips of <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">suspicious characters.</span> »</span> If you’re thinking that this
1681 sounds like a recipe for letting curtain-twitching racists supercharge their
1682 suspicions of people with brown skin who walk down their blocks, <a class="ulink" href="https://www.eff.org/deeplinks/2020/07/amazons-ring-enables-over-policing-efforts-some-americas-deadliest-law-enforcement" target="_top">you’re
1683 right</a>. Ring has become a <span class="emphasis"><em>de facto,</em></span>
1684 off-the-books arm of the police without any of the pesky oversight or rules.
1685 </p><p>
1686 In mid-2019, a series of public records requests revealed that Amazon had
1687 struck confidential deals with more than 400 local law enforcement agencies
1688 through which the agencies would promote Ring and Neighbors and in exchange
1689 get access to footage from Ring cameras. In theory, cops would need to
1690 request this footage through Amazon (and internal documents reveal that
1691 Amazon devotes substantial resources to coaching cops on how to spin a
1692 convincing story when doing so), but in practice, when a Ring customer turns
1693 down a police request, Amazon only requires the agency to formally request
1694 the footage from the company, which it will then produce.
1695 </p><p>
1696 Ring and law enforcement have found many ways to intertwine their
1697 activities. Ring strikes secret deals to acquire real-time access to 911
1698 dispatch and then streams alarming crime reports to Neighbors users, which
1699 serve as convincers for anyone who’s contemplating a surveillance doorbell
1700 but isn’t sure whether their neighborhood is dangerous enough to warrant it.
1701 </p><p>
1702 The more the cops buzz-market the surveillance capitalist Ring, the more
1703 surveillance capability the state gets. Cops who rely on private entities
1704 for law-enforcement roles then brief against any controls on the deployment
1705 of that technology while the companies return the favor by lobbying against
1706 rules requiring public oversight of police surveillance technology. The more
1707 the cops rely on Ring and Neighbors, the harder it will be to pass laws to
1708 curb them. The fewer laws there are against them, the more the cops will
1709 rely on them.
1710 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="dignity-and-sanctuary"></a>Dignity and sanctuary</h2></div></div></div><p>
1711 But even if we could exercise democratic control over our states and force
1712 them to stop raiding surveillance capitalism’s reservoirs of behavioral
1713 data, surveillance capitalism would still harm us.
1714 </p><p>
1715 This is an area where Zuboff shines. Her chapter on <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">sanctuary</span> »</span>
1716 — the feeling of being unobserved — is a beautiful hymn to introspection,
1717 calmness, mindfulness, and tranquility.
1718 </p><p>
1719 When you are watched, something changes. Anyone who has ever raised a child
1720 knows this. You might look up from your book (or more realistically, from
1721 your phone) and catch your child in a moment of profound realization and
1722 growth, a moment where they are learning something that is right at the edge
1723 of their abilities, requiring their entire ferocious concentration. For a
1724 moment, you’re transfixed, watching that rare and beautiful moment of focus
1725 playing out before your eyes, and then your child looks up and sees you
1726 seeing them, and the moment collapses. To grow, you need to be and expose
1727 your authentic self, and in that moment, you are vulnerable like a hermit
1728 crab scuttling from one shell to the next. The tender, unprotected tissues
1729 you expose in that moment are too delicate to reveal in the presence of
1730 another, even someone you trust as implicitly as a child trusts their
1731 parent.
1732 </p><p>
1733 In the digital age, our authentic selves are inextricably tied to our
1734 digital lives. Your search history is a running ledger of the questions
1735 you’ve pondered. Your location history is a record of the places you’ve
1736 sought out and the experiences you’ve had there. Your social graph reveals
1737 the different facets of your identity, the people you’ve connected with.
1738 </p><p>
1739 To be observed in these activities is to lose the sanctuary of your
1740 authentic self.
1741 </p><p>
1742 There’s another way in which surveillance capitalism robs us of our capacity
1743 to be our authentic selves: by making us anxious. Surveillance capitalism
1744 isn’t really a mind-control ray, but you don’t need a mind-control ray to
1745 make someone anxious. After all, another word for anxiety is agitation, and
1746 to make someone experience agitation, you need merely to agitate them. To
1747 poke them and prod them and beep at them and buzz at them and bombard them
1748 on an intermittent schedule that is just random enough that our limbic
1749 systems never quite become inured to it.
1750 </p><p>
1751 Our devices and services are <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">general purpose</span> »</span> in that they can
1752 connect anything or anyone to anything or anyone else and that they can run
1753 any program that can be written. This means that the distraction rectangles
1754 in our pockets hold our most precious moments with our most beloved people
1755 and their most urgent or time-sensitive communications (from <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">running
1756 late can you get the kid?</span> »</span> to <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">doctor gave me bad news and I
1757 need to talk to you RIGHT NOW</span> »</span>) as well as ads for refrigerators and
1758 recruiting messages from Nazis.
1759 </p><p>
1760 All day and all night, our pockets buzz, shattering our concentration and
1761 tearing apart the fragile webs of connection we spin as we think through
1762 difficult ideas. If you locked someone in a cell and agitated them like
1763 this, we’d call it <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">sleep deprivation torture,</span> »</span> and it would be
1764 <a class="ulink" href="https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=1SKpRbvnx6g" target="_top">a war crime under
1765 the Geneva Conventions</a>.
1766 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="afflicting-the-afflicted"></a>Afflicting the afflicted</h2></div></div></div><p>
1767 The effects of surveillance on our ability to be our authentic selves are
1768 not equal for all people. Some of us are lucky enough to live in a time and
1769 place in which all the most important facts of our lives are widely and
1770 roundly socially acceptable and can be publicly displayed without the risk
1771 of social consequence.
1772 </p><p>
1773 But for many of us, this is not true. Recall that in living memory, many of
1774 the ways of being that we think of as socially acceptable today were once
1775 cause for dire social sanction or even imprisonment. If you are 65 years
1776 old, you have lived through a time in which people living in <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">free
1777 societies</span> »</span> could be imprisoned or sanctioned for engaging in
1778 homosexual activity, for falling in love with a person whose skin was a
1779 different color than their own, or for smoking weed.
1780 </p><p>
1781 Today, these activities aren’t just decriminalized in much of the world,
1782 they’re considered normal, and the fallen prohibitions are viewed as
1783 shameful, regrettable relics of the past.
1784 </p><p>
1785 How did we get from prohibition to normalization? Through private, personal
1786 activity: People who were secretly gay or secret pot-smokers or who secretly
1787 loved someone with a different skin color were vulnerable to retaliation if
1788 they made their true selves known and were limited in how much they could
1789 advocate for their own right to exist in the world and be true to
1790 themselves. But because there was a private sphere, these people could form
1791 alliances with their friends and loved ones who did not share their
1792 disfavored traits by having private conversations in which they came out,
1793 disclosing their true selves to the people around them and bringing them to
1794 their cause one conversation at a time.
1795 </p><p>
1796 The right to choose the time and manner of these conversations was key to
1797 their success. It’s one thing to come out to your dad while you’re on a
1798 fishing trip away from the world and another thing entirely to blurt it out
1799 over the Christmas dinner table while your racist Facebook uncle is there to
1800 make a scene.
1801 </p><p>
1802 Without a private sphere, there’s a chance that none of these changes would
1803 have come to pass and that the people who benefited from these changes would
1804 have either faced social sanction for coming out to a hostile world or would
1805 have never been able to reveal their true selves to the people they love.
1806 </p><p>
1807 The corollary is that, unless you think that our society has attained social
1808 perfection — that your grandchildren in 50 years will ask you to tell them
1809 the story of how, in 2020, every injustice had been righted and no further
1810 change had to be made — then you should expect that right now, at this
1811 minute, there are people you love, whose happiness is key to your own, who
1812 have a secret in their hearts that stops them from ever being their
1813 authentic selves with you. These people are sorrowing and will go to their
1814 graves with that secret sorrow in their hearts, and the source of that
1815 sorrow will be the falsity of their relationship to you.
1816 </p><p>
1817 A private realm is necessary for human progress.
1818 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="any-data-you-collect-and-retain-will-eventually-leak"></a>Any data you collect and retain will eventually leak</h2></div></div></div><p>
1819 The lack of a private life can rob vulnerable people of the chance to be
1820 their authentic selves and constrain our actions by depriving us of
1821 sanctuary, but there is another risk that is borne by everyone, not just
1822 people with a secret: crime.
1823 </p><p>
1824 Personally identifying information is of very limited use for the purpose of
1825 controlling peoples’ minds, but identity theft — really a catchall term for
1826 a whole constellation of terrible criminal activities that can destroy your
1827 finances, compromise your personal integrity, ruin your reputation, or even
1828 expose you to physical danger — thrives on it.
1829 </p><p>
1830 Attackers are not limited to using data from one breached source,
1831 either. Multiple services have suffered breaches that exposed names,
1832 addresses, phone numbers, passwords, sexual tastes, school grades, work
1833 performance, brushes with the criminal justice system, family details,
1834 genetic information, fingerprints and other biometrics, reading habits,
1835 search histories, literary tastes, pseudonymous identities, and other
1836 sensitive information. Attackers can merge data from these different
1837 breaches to build up extremely detailed dossiers on random subjects and then
1838 use different parts of the data for different criminal purposes.
1839 </p><p>
1840 For example, attackers can use leaked username and password combinations to
1841 hijack whole fleets of commercial vehicles that <a class="ulink" href="https://www.vice.com/en_us/article/zmpx4x/hacker-monitor-cars-kill-engine-gps-tracking-apps" target="_top">have
1842 been fitted with anti-theft GPS trackers and immobilizers</a> or to
1843 hijack baby monitors in order to <a class="ulink" href="https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/04/23/how-nest-designed-keep-intruders-out-peoples-homes-effectively-allowed-hackers-get/?utm_term=.15220e98c550" target="_top">terrorize
1844 toddlers with the audio tracks from pornography</a>. Attackers use
1845 leaked data to trick phone companies into giving them your phone number,
1846 then they intercept SMS-based two-factor authentication codes in order to
1847 take over your email, bank account, and/or cryptocurrency wallets.
1848 </p><p>
1849 Attackers are endlessly inventive in the pursuit of creative ways to
1850 weaponize leaked data. One common use of leaked data is to penetrate
1851 companies in order to access <span class="emphasis"><em>more</em></span> data.
1852 </p><p>
1853 Like spies, online fraudsters are totally dependent on companies
1854 over-collecting and over-retaining our data. Spy agencies sometimes pay
1855 companies for access to their data or intimidate them into giving it up, but
1856 sometimes they work just like criminals do — by <a class="ulink" href="https://www.bbc.com/news/world-us-canada-24751821" target="_top">sneaking data out of
1857 companies’ databases</a>.
1858 </p><p>
1859 The over-collection of data has a host of terrible social consequences, from
1860 the erosion of our authentic selves to the undermining of social progress,
1861 from state surveillance to an epidemic of online crime. Commercial
1862 surveillance is also a boon to people running influence campaigns, but
1863 that’s the least of our troubles.
1864 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="critical-tech-exceptionalism-is-still-tech-exceptionalism"></a>Critical tech exceptionalism is still tech exceptionalism</h2></div></div></div><p>
1865 Big Tech has long practiced technology exceptionalism: the idea that it
1866 should not be subject to the mundane laws and norms of
1867 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">meatspace.</span> »</span> Mottoes like Facebook’s <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">move fast and break
1868 things</span> »</span> attracted justifiable scorn of the companies’ self-serving
1869 rhetoric.
1870 </p><p>
1871 Tech exceptionalism got us all into a lot of trouble, so it’s ironic and
1872 distressing to see Big Tech’s critics committing the same sin.
1873 </p><p>
1874 Big Tech is not a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism</span> »</span> that cannot be cured
1875 through the traditional anti-monopoly remedies of trustbusting (forcing
1876 companies to divest of competitors they have acquired) and bans on mergers
1877 to monopoly and other anti-competitive tactics. Big Tech does not have the
1878 power to use machine learning to influence our behavior so thoroughly that
1879 markets lose the ability to punish bad actors and reward superior
1880 competitors. Big Tech has no rule-writing mind-control ray that necessitates
1881 ditching our old toolbox.
1882 </p><p>
1883 The thing is, people have been claiming to have perfected mind-control rays
1884 for centuries, and every time, it turned out to be a con — though sometimes
1885 the con artists were also conning themselves.
1886 </p><p>
1887 For generations, the advertising industry has been steadily improving its
1888 ability to sell advertising services to businesses while only making
1889 marginal gains in selling those businesses’ products to prospective
1890 customers. John Wanamaker’s lament that <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">50% of my advertising budget
1891 is wasted, I just don’t know which 50%</span> »</span> is a testament to the triumph
1892 of <span class="emphasis"><em>ad executives</em></span>, who successfully convinced Wanamaker
1893 that only half of the money he spent went to waste.
1894 </p><p>
1895 The tech industry has made enormous improvements in the science of
1896 convincing businesses that they’re good at advertising while their actual
1897 improvements to advertising — as opposed to targeting — have been pretty
1898 ho-hum. The vogue for machine learning — and the mystical invocation of
1899 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">artificial intelligence</span> »</span> as a synonym for straightforward
1900 statistical inference techniques — has greatly boosted the efficacy of Big
1901 Tech’s sales pitch as marketers have exploited potential customers’ lack of
1902 technical sophistication to get away with breathtaking acts of overpromising
1903 and underdelivering.
1904 </p><p>
1905 It’s tempting to think that if businesses are willing to pour billions into
1906 a venture that the venture must be a good one. Yet there are plenty of times
1907 when this rule of thumb has led us astray. For example, it’s virtually
1908 unheard of for managed investment funds to outperform simple index funds,
1909 and investors who put their money into the hands of expert money managers
1910 overwhelmingly fare worse than those who entrust their savings to index
1911 funds. But managed funds still account for the majority of the money
1912 invested in the markets, and they are patronized by some of the richest,
1913 most sophisticated investors in the world. Their vote of confidence in an
1914 underperforming sector is a parable about the role of luck in wealth
1915 accumulation, not a sign that managed funds are a good buy.
1916 </p><p>
1917 The claims of Big Tech’s mind-control system are full of tells that the
1918 enterprise is a con. For example, <a class="ulink" href="https://www.frontiersin.org/articles/10.3389/fpsyg.2020.01415/full" target="_top">the
1919 reliance on the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Big Five</span> »</span> personality traits</a> as a
1920 primary means of influencing people even though the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Big Five</span> »</span>
1921 theory is unsupported by any large-scale, peer-reviewed studies and is
1922 <a class="ulink" href="https://www.wired.com/story/the-noisy-fallacies-of-psychographic-targeting/" target="_top">mostly
1923 the realm of marketing hucksters and pop psych</a>.
1924 </p><p>
1925 Big Tech’s promotional materials also claim that their algorithms can
1926 accurately perform <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">sentiment analysis</span> »</span> or detect peoples’
1927 moods based on their <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">microexpressions,</span> »</span> but <a class="ulink" href="https://www.npr.org/2018/09/12/647040758/advertising-on-facebook-is-it-worth-it" target="_top">these
1928 are marketing claims, not scientific ones</a>. These methods are largely
1929 untested by independent scientific experts, and where they have been tested,
1930 they’ve been found sorely wanting. Microexpressions are particularly
1931 suspect as the companies that specialize in training people to detect them
1932 <a class="ulink" href="https://theintercept.com/2017/02/08/tsas-own-files-show-doubtful-science-behind-its-behavior-screening-program/" target="_top">have
1933 been shown</a> to underperform relative to random chance.
1934 </p><p>
1935 Big Tech has been so good at marketing its own supposed superpowers that
1936 it’s easy to believe that they can market everything else with similar
1937 acumen, but it’s a mistake to believe the hype. Any statement a company
1938 makes about the quality of its products is clearly not impartial. The fact
1939 that we distrust all the things that Big Tech says about its data handling,
1940 compliance with privacy laws, etc., is only reasonable — but why on Earth
1941 would we treat Big Tech’s marketing literature as the gospel truth? Big Tech
1942 lies about just about <span class="emphasis"><em>everything</em></span>, including how well
1943 its machine-learning fueled persuasion systems work.
1944 </p><p>
1945 That skepticism should infuse all of our evaluations of Big Tech and its
1946 supposed abilities, including our perusal of its patents. Zuboff vests these
1947 patents with enormous significance, pointing out that Google claimed
1948 extensive new persuasion capabilities in <a class="ulink" href="https://patents.google.com/patent/US20050131762A1/en" target="_top">its patent
1949 filings</a>. These claims are doubly suspect: first, because they are so
1950 self-serving, and second, because the patent itself is so notoriously an
1951 invitation to exaggeration.
1952 </p><p>
1953 Patent applications take the form of a series of claims and range from broad
1954 to narrow. A typical patent starts out by claiming that its authors have
1955 invented a method or system for doing every conceivable thing that anyone
1956 might do, ever, with any tool or device. Then it narrows that claim in
1957 successive stages until we get to the actual <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">invention</span> »</span> that
1958 is the true subject of the patent. The hope is that the patent examiner —
1959 who is almost certainly overworked and underinformed — will miss the fact
1960 that some or all of these claims are ridiculous, or at least suspect, and
1961 grant the patent’s broader claims. Patents for unpatentable things are still
1962 incredibly useful because they can be wielded against competitors who might
1963 license that patent or steer clear of its claims rather than endure the
1964 lengthy, expensive process of contesting it.
1965 </p><p>
1966 What’s more, software patents are routinely granted even though the filer
1967 doesn’t have any evidence that they can do the thing claimed by the
1968 patent. That is, you can patent an <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">invention</span> »</span> that you haven’t
1969 actually made and that you don’t know how to make.
1970 </p><p>
1971 With these considerations in hand, it becomes obvious that the fact that a
1972 Big Tech company has patented what it <span class="emphasis"><em>says</em></span> is an
1973 effective mind-control ray is largely irrelevant to whether Big Tech can in
1974 fact control our minds.
1975 </p><p>
1976 Big Tech collects our data for many reasons, including the diminishing
1977 returns on existing stores of data. But many tech companies also collect
1978 data out of a mistaken tech exceptionalist belief in the network effects of
1979 data. Network effects occur when each new user in a system increases its
1980 value. The classic example is fax machines: A single fax machine is of no
1981 use, two fax machines are of limited use, but every new fax machine that’s
1982 put to use after the first doubles the number of possible fax-to-fax links.
1983 </p><p>
1984 Data mined for predictive systems doesn’t necessarily produce these
1985 dividends. Think of Netflix: The predictive value of the data mined from a
1986 million English-speaking Netflix viewers is hardly improved by the addition
1987 of one more user’s viewing data. Most of the data Netflix acquires after
1988 that first minimum viable sample duplicates existing data and produces only
1989 minimal gains. Meanwhile, retraining models with new data gets progressively
1990 more expensive as the number of data points increases, and manual tasks like
1991 labeling and validating data do not get cheaper at scale.
1992 </p><p>
1993 Businesses pursue fads to the detriment of their profits all the time,
1994 especially when the businesses and their investors are not motivated by the
1995 prospect of becoming profitable but rather by the prospect of being acquired
1996 by a Big Tech giant or by having an IPO. For these firms, ticking faddish
1997 boxes like <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">collects as much data as possible</span> »</span> might realize a
1998 bigger return on investment than <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">collects a business-appropriate
1999 quantity of data.</span> »</span>
2000 </p><p>
2001 This is another harm of tech exceptionalism: The belief that more data
2002 always produces more profits in the form of more insights that can be
2003 translated into better mind-control rays drives firms to over-collect and
2004 over-retain data beyond all rationality. And since the firms are behaving
2005 irrationally, a good number of them will go out of business and become ghost
2006 ships whose cargo holds are stuffed full of data that can harm people in
2007 myriad ways — but which no one is responsible for antey longer. Even if the
2008 companies don’t go under, the data they collect is maintained behind the
2009 minimum viable security — just enough security to keep the company viable
2010 while it waits to get bought out by a tech giant, an amount calculated to
2011 spend not one penny more than is necessary on protecting data.
2012 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="how-monopolies-not-mind-control-drive-surveillance-capitalism-the-snapchat-story"></a>How monopolies, not mind control, drive surveillance capitalism: The
2013 Snapchat story</h2></div></div></div><p>
2014 For the first decade of its existence, Facebook competed with the social
2015 media giants of the day (Myspace, Orkut, etc.) by presenting itself as the
2016 pro-privacy alternative. Indeed, Facebook justified its walled garden —
2017 which let users bring in data from the web but blocked web services like
2018 Google Search from indexing and caching Facebook pages — as a pro-privacy
2019 measure that protected users from the surveillance-happy winners of the
2020 social media wars like Myspace.
2021 </p><p>
2022 Despite frequent promises that it would never collect or analyze its users’
2023 data, Facebook periodically created initiatives that did just that, like the
2024 creepy, ham-fisted Beacon tool, which spied on you as you moved around the
2025 web and then added your online activities to your public timeline, allowing
2026 your friends to monitor your browsing habits. Beacon sparked a user
2027 revolt. Every time, Facebook backed off from its surveillance initiative,
2028 but not all the way; inevitably, the new Facebook would be more surveilling
2029 than the old Facebook, though not quite as surveilling as the intermediate
2030 Facebook following the launch of the new product or service.
2031 </p><p>
2032 The pace at which Facebook ramped up its surveillance efforts seems to have
2033 been set by Facebook’s competitive landscape. The more competitors Facebook
2034 had, the better it behaved. Every time a major competitor foundered,
2035 Facebook’s behavior <a class="ulink" href="https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3247362" target="_top">got
2036 markedly worse</a>.
2037 </p><p>
2038 All the while, Facebook was prodigiously acquiring companies, including a
2039 company called Onavo. Nominally, Onavo made a battery-monitoring mobile
2040 app. But the permissions that Onavo required were so expansive that the app
2041 was able to gather fine-grained telemetry on everything users did with their
2042 phones, including which apps they used and how they were using them.
2043 </p><p>
2044 Through Onavo, Facebook discovered that it was losing market share to
2045 Snapchat, an app that — like Facebook a decade before — billed itself as the
2046 pro-privacy alternative to the status quo. Through Onavo, Facebook was able
2047 to mine data from the devices of Snapchat users, including both current and
2048 former Snapchat users. This spurred Facebook to acquire Instagram — some
2049 features of which competed with Snapchat — and then allowed Facebook to
2050 fine-tune Instagram’s features and sales pitch to erode Snapchat’s gains and
2051 ensure that Facebook would not have to face the kinds of competitive
2052 pressures it had earlier inflicted on Myspace and Orkut.
2053 </p><p>
2054 The story of how Facebook crushed Snapchat reveals the relationship between
2055 monopoly and surveillance capitalism. Facebook combined surveillance with
2056 lax antitrust enforcement to spot the competitive threat of Snapchat on its
2057 horizon and then take decisive action against it. Facebook’s surveillance
2058 capitalism let it avert competitive pressure with anti-competitive
2059 tactics. Facebook users still want privacy — Facebook hasn’t used
2060 surveillance to brainwash them out of it — but they can’t get it because
2061 Facebook’s surveillance lets it destroy any hope of a rival service emerging
2062 that competes on privacy features.
2063 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="a-monopoly-over-your-friends"></a>A monopoly over your friends</h2></div></div></div><p>
2064 A decentralization movement has tried to erode the dominance of Facebook and
2065 other Big Tech companies by fielding <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">indieweb</span> »</span> alternatives —
2066 Mastodon as a Twitter alternative, Diaspora as a Facebook alternative,
2067 etc. — but these efforts have failed to attain any kind of liftoff.
2068 </p><p>
2069 Fundamentally, each of these services is hamstrung by the same problem:
2070 Every potential user for a Facebook or Twitter alternative has to convince
2071 all their friends to follow them to a decentralized web alternative in order
2072 to continue to realize the benefit of social media. For many of us, the only
2073 reason to have a Facebook account is that our friends have Facebook
2074 accounts, and the reason they have Facebook accounts is that
2075 <span class="emphasis"><em>we</em></span> have Facebook accounts.
2076 </p><p>
2077 All of this has conspired to make Facebook — and other dominant platforms —
2078 into <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">kill zones</span> »</span> that investors will not fund new entrants
2079 for.
2080 </p><p>
2081 And yet, all of today’s tech giants came into existence despite the
2082 entrenched advantage of the companies that came before them. To understand
2083 how that happened, you have to understand both interoperability and
2084 adversarial interoperability.
2085 </p><div class="blockquote"><blockquote class="blockquote"><p>
2086 The hard problem of our species is coordination.
2087 </p></blockquote></div><p>
2088 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Interoperability</span> »</span> is the ability of two technologies to work
2089 with one another: Anyone can make an LP that will play on any record player,
2090 anyone can make a filter you can install in your stove’s extractor fan,
2091 anyone can make gasoline for your car, anyone can make a USB phone charger
2092 that fits in your car’s cigarette lighter receptacle, anyone can make a
2093 light bulb that works in your light socket, anyone can make bread that will
2094 toast in your toaster.
2095 </p><p>
2096 Interoperability is often a source of innovation and consumer benefit: Apple
2097 made the first commercially successful PC, but millions of independent
2098 software vendors made interoperable programs that ran on the Apple II
2099 Plus. The simple analog antenna inputs on the back of TVs first allowed
2100 cable operators to connect directly to TVs, then they allowed game console
2101 companies and then personal computer companies to use standard televisions
2102 as displays. Standard RJ-11 telephone jacks allowed for the production of
2103 phones from a variety of vendors in a variety of forms, from the free
2104 football-shaped phone that came with a <span class="emphasis"><em>Sports
2105 Illustrated</em></span> subscription to business phones with speakers, hold
2106 functions, and so on and then answering machines and finally modems, paving
2107 the way for the internet revolution.
2108 </p><p>
2109 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Interoperability</span> »</span> is often used interchangeably with
2110 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">standardization,</span> »</span> which is the process when manufacturers and
2111 other stakeholders hammer out a set of agreed-upon rules for implementing a
2112 technology, such as the electrical plug on your wall, the CAN bus used by
2113 your car’s computer systems, or the HTML instructions that your browser
2114 interprets.
2115 </p><p>
2116 But interoperability doesn’t require standardization — indeed,
2117 standardization often proceeds from the chaos of ad hoc interoperability
2118 measures. The inventor of the cigarette-lighter USB charger didn’t need to
2119 get permission from car manufacturers or even the manufacturers of the
2120 dashboard lighter subcomponent. The automakers didn’t take any
2121 countermeasures to prevent the use of these aftermarket accessories by their
2122 customers, but they also didn’t do anything to make life easier for the
2123 chargers’ manufacturers. This is a kind of <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">neutral
2124 interoperability.</span> »</span>
2125 </p><p>
2126 Beyond neutral interoperability, there is <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">adversarial
2127 interoperability.</span> »</span> That’s when a manufacturer makes a product that
2128 interoperates with another manufacturer’s product <span class="emphasis"><em>despite the
2129 second manufacturer’s objections</em></span> and <span class="emphasis"><em>even if that means
2130 bypassing a security system designed to prevent interoperability</em></span>.
2131 </p><p>
2132 Probably the most familiar form of adversarial interoperability is
2133 third-party printer ink. Printer manufacturers claim that they sell printers
2134 below cost and that the only way they can recoup the losses they incur is by
2135 charging high markups on ink. To prevent the owners of printers from buying
2136 ink elsewhere, the printer companies deploy a suite of anti-customer
2137 security systems that detect and reject both refilled and third-party
2138 cartridges.
2139 </p><p>
2140 Owners of printers take the position that HP and Epson and Brother are not
2141 charities and that customers for their wares have no obligation to help them
2142 survive, and so if the companies choose to sell their products at a loss,
2143 that’s their foolish choice and their consequences to live with. Likewise,
2144 competitors who make ink or refill kits observe that they don’t owe printer
2145 companies anything, and their erosion of printer companies’ margins are the
2146 printer companies’ problems, not their competitors’. After all, the printer
2147 companies shed no tears when they drive a refiller out of business, so why
2148 should the refillers concern themselves with the economic fortunes of the
2149 printer companies?
2150 </p><p>
2151 Adversarial interoperability has played an outsized role in the history of
2152 the tech industry: from the founding of the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">alt.*</span> »</span> Usenet
2153 hierarchy (which was started against the wishes of Usenet’s maintainers and
2154 which grew to be bigger than all of Usenet combined) to the browser wars
2155 (when Netscape and Microsoft devoted massive engineering efforts to making
2156 their browsers incompatible with the other’s special commands and
2157 peccadilloes) to Facebook (whose success was built in part by helping its
2158 new users stay in touch with friends they’d left behind on Myspace because
2159 Facebook supplied them with a tool that scraped waiting messages from
2160 Myspace and imported them into Facebook, effectively creating an
2161 Facebook-based Myspace reader).
2162 </p><p>
2163 Today, incumbency is seen as an unassailable advantage. Facebook is where
2164 all of your friends are, so no one can start a Facebook competitor. But
2165 adversarial compatibility reverses the competitive advantage: If you were
2166 allowed to compete with Facebook by providing a tool that imported all your
2167 users’ waiting Facebook messages into an environment that competed on lines
2168 that Facebook couldn’t cross, like eliminating surveillance and ads, then
2169 Facebook would be at a huge disadvantage. It would have assembled all
2170 possible ex-Facebook users into a single, easy-to-find service; it would
2171 have educated them on how a Facebook-like service worked and what its
2172 potential benefits were; and it would have provided an easy means for
2173 disgruntled Facebook users to tell their friends where they might expect
2174 better treatment.
2175 </p><p>
2176 Adversarial interoperability was once the norm and a key contributor to the
2177 dynamic, vibrant tech scene, but now it is stuck behind a thicket of laws
2178 and regulations that add legal risks to the tried-and-true tactics of
2179 adversarial interoperability. New rules and new interpretations of existing
2180 rules mean that a would-be adversarial interoperator needs to steer clear of
2181 claims under copyright, terms of service, trade secrecy, tortious
2182 interference, and patent.
2183 </p><p>
2184 In the absence of a competitive market, lawmakers have resorted to assigning
2185 expensive, state-like duties to Big Tech firms, such as automatically
2186 filtering user contributions for copyright infringement or terrorist and
2187 extremist content or detecting and preventing harassment in real time or
2188 controlling access to sexual material.
2189 </p><p>
2190 These measures put a floor under how small we can make Big Tech because only
2191 the very largest companies can afford the humans and automated filters
2192 needed to perform these duties.
2193 </p><p>
2194 But that’s not the only way in which making platforms responsible for
2195 policing their users undermines competition. A platform that is expected to
2196 police its users’ conduct must prevent many vital adversarial
2197 interoperability techniques lest these subvert its policing measures. For
2198 example, if someone using a Twitter replacement like Mastodon is able to
2199 push messages into Twitter and read messages out of Twitter, they could
2200 avoid being caught by automated systems that detect and prevent harassment
2201 (such as systems that use the timing of messages or IP-based rules to make
2202 guesses about whether someone is a harasser).
2203 </p><p>
2204 To the extent that we are willing to let Big Tech police itself — rather
2205 than making Big Tech small enough that users can leave bad platforms for
2206 better ones and small enough that a regulation that simply puts a platform
2207 out of business will not destroy billions of users’ access to their
2208 communities and data — we build the case that Big Tech should be able to
2209 block its competitors and make it easier for Big Tech to demand legal
2210 enforcement tools to ban and punish attempts at adversarial
2211 interoperability.
2212 </p><p>
2213 Ultimately, we can try to fix Big Tech by making it responsible for bad acts
2214 by its users, or we can try to fix the internet by cutting Big Tech down to
2215 size. But we can’t do both. To replace today’s giant products with
2216 pluralistic protocols, we need to clear the legal thicket that prevents
2217 adversarial interoperability so that tomorrow’s nimble, personal,
2218 small-scale products can federate themselves with giants like Facebook,
2219 allowing the users who’ve left to continue to communicate with users who
2220 haven’t left yet, reaching tendrils over Facebook’s garden wall that
2221 Facebook’s trapped users can use to scale the walls and escape to the
2222 global, open web.
2223 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="fake-news-is-an-epistemological-crisis"></a>Fake news is an epistemological crisis</h2></div></div></div><p>
2224 Tech is not the only industry that has undergone massive concentration since
2225 the Reagan era. Virtually every major industry — from oil to newspapers to
2226 meatpacking to sea freight to eyewear to online pornography — has become a
2227 clubby oligarchy that just a few players dominate.
2228 </p><p>
2229 At the same time, every industry has become something of a tech industry as
2230 general-purpose computers and general-purpose networks and the promise of
2231 efficiencies through data-driven analysis infuse every device, process, and
2232 firm with tech.
2233 </p><p>
2234 This phenomenon of industrial concentration is part of a wider story about
2235 wealth concentration overall as a smaller and smaller number of people own
2236 more and more of our world. This concentration of both wealth and industries
2237 means that our political outcomes are increasingly beholden to the parochial
2238 interests of the people and companies with all the money.
2239 </p><p>
2240 That means that whenever a regulator asks a question with an obvious,
2241 empirical answer (<span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Are humans causing climate change?</span> »</span> or
2242 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Should we let companies conduct commercial mass surveillance?</span> »</span>
2243 or <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Does society benefit from allowing network neutrality
2244 violations?</span> »</span>), the answer that comes out is only correct if that
2245 correctness meets with the approval of rich people and the industries that
2246 made them so wealthy.
2247 </p><p>
2248 Rich people have always played an outsized role in politics and more so
2249 since the Supreme Court’s <span class="emphasis"><em>Citizens United</em></span> decision
2250 eliminated key controls over political spending. Widening inequality and
2251 wealth concentration means that the very richest people are now a lot richer
2252 and can afford to spend a lot more money on political projects than ever
2253 before. Think of the Koch brothers or George Soros or Bill Gates.
2254 </p><p>
2255 But the policy distortions of rich individuals pale in comparison to the
2256 policy distortions that concentrated industries are capable of. The
2257 companies in highly concentrated industries are much more profitable than
2258 companies in competitive industries — no competition means not having to
2259 reduce prices or improve quality to win customers — leaving them with bigger
2260 capital surpluses to spend on lobbying.
2261 </p><p>
2262 Concentrated industries also find it easier to collaborate on policy
2263 objectives than competitive ones. When all the top execs from your industry
2264 can fit around a single boardroom table, they often do. And
2265 <span class="emphasis"><em>when</em></span> they do, they can forge a consensus position on
2266 regulation.
2267 </p><p>
2268 Rising through the ranks in a concentrated industry generally means working
2269 at two or three of the big companies. When there are only relatively few
2270 companies in a given industry, each company has a more ossified executive
2271 rank, leaving ambitious execs with fewer paths to higher positions unless
2272 they are recruited to a rival. This means that the top execs in concentrated
2273 industries are likely to have been colleagues at some point and socialize in
2274 the same circles — connected through social ties or, say, serving as
2275 trustees for each others’ estates. These tight social bonds foster a
2276 collegial, rather than competitive, attitude.
2277 </p><p>
2278 Highly concentrated industries also present a regulatory conundrum. When an
2279 industry is dominated by just four or five companies, the only people who
2280 are likely to truly understand the industry’s practices are its veteran
2281 executives. This means that top regulators are often former execs of the
2282 companies they are supposed to be regulating. These turns in government are
2283 often tacitly understood to be leaves of absence from industry, with former
2284 employers welcoming their erstwhile watchdogs back into their executive
2285 ranks once their terms have expired.
2286 </p><p>
2287 All this is to say that the tight social bonds, small number of firms, and
2288 regulatory capture of concentrated industries give the companies that
2289 comprise them the power to dictate many, if not all, of the regulations that
2290 bind them.
2291 </p><p>
2292 This is increasingly obvious. Whether it’s payday lenders <a class="ulink" href="https://www.washingtonpost.com/business/2019/02/25/how-payday-lending-industry-insider-tilted-academic-research-its-favor/" target="_top">winning
2293 the right to practice predatory lending</a> or Apple <a class="ulink" href="https://www.vice.com/en_us/article/mgxayp/source-apple-will-fight-right-to-repair-legislation" target="_top">winning
2294 the right to decide who can fix your phone</a> or Google and Facebook
2295 winning the right to breach your private data without suffering meaningful
2296 consequences or victories for pipeline companies or impunity for opioid
2297 manufacturers or massive tax subsidies for incredibly profitable dominant
2298 businesses, it’s increasingly apparent that many of our official,
2299 evidence-based truth-seeking processes are, in fact, auctions for sale to
2300 the highest bidder.
2301 </p><p>
2302 It’s really impossible to overstate what a terrifying prospect this is. We
2303 live in an incredibly high-tech society, and none of us could acquire the
2304 expertise to evaluate every technological proposition that stands between us
2305 and our untimely, horrible deaths. You might devote your life to acquiring
2306 the media literacy to distinguish good scientific journals from corrupt
2307 pay-for-play lookalikes and the statistical literacy to evaluate the quality
2308 of the analysis in the journals as well as the microbiology and epidemiology
2309 knowledge to determine whether you can trust claims about the safety of
2310 vaccines — but that would still leave you unqualified to judge whether the
2311 wiring in your home will give you a lethal shock <span class="emphasis"><em>and</em></span>
2312 whether your car’s brakes’ software will cause them to fail unpredictably
2313 <span class="emphasis"><em>and</em></span> whether the hygiene standards at your butcher are
2314 sufficient to keep you from dying after you finish your dinner.
2315 </p><p>
2316 In a world as complex as this one, we have to defer to authorities, and we
2317 keep them honest by making those authorities accountable to us and binding
2318 them with rules to prevent conflicts of interest. We can’t possibly acquire
2319 the expertise to adjudicate conflicting claims about the best way to make
2320 the world safe and prosperous, but we <span class="emphasis"><em>can</em></span> determine
2321 whether the adjudication process itself is trustworthy.
2322 </p><p>
2323 Right now, it’s obviously not.
2324 </p><p>
2325 The past 40 years of rising inequality and industry concentration, together
2326 with increasingly weak accountability and transparency for expert agencies,
2327 has created an increasingly urgent sense of impending doom, the sense that
2328 there are vast conspiracies afoot that operate with tacit official approval
2329 despite the likelihood they are working to better themselves by ruining the
2330 rest of us.
2331 </p><p>
2332 For example, it’s been decades since Exxon’s own scientists concluded that
2333 its products would render the Earth uninhabitable by humans. And yet those
2334 decades were lost to us, in large part because Exxon lobbied governments and
2335 sowed doubt about the dangers of its products and did so with the
2336 cooperation of many public officials. When the survival of you and everyone
2337 you love is threatened by conspiracies, it’s not unreasonable to start
2338 questioning the things you think you know in an attempt to determine whether
2339 they, too, are the outcome of another conspiracy.
2340 </p><p>
2341 The collapse of the credibility of our systems for divining and upholding
2342 truths has left us in a state of epistemological chaos. Once, most of us
2343 might have assumed that the system was working and that our regulations
2344 reflected our best understanding of the empirical truths of the world as
2345 they were best understood — now we have to find our own experts to help us
2346 sort the true from the false.
2347 </p><p>
2348 If you’re like me, you probably believe that vaccines are safe, but you
2349 (like me) probably also can’t explain the microbiology or statistics. Few of
2350 us have the math skills to review the literature on vaccine safety and
2351 describe why their statistical reasoning is sound. Likewise, few of us can
2352 review the stats in the (now discredited) literature on opioid safety and
2353 explain how those stats were manipulated. Both vaccines and opioids were
2354 embraced by medical authorities, after all, and one is safe while the other
2355 could ruin your life. You’re left with a kind of inchoate constellation of
2356 rules of thumb about which experts you trust to fact-check controversial
2357 claims and then to explain how all those respectable doctors with their
2358 peer-reviewed research on opioid safety <span class="emphasis"><em>were</em></span> an
2359 aberration and then how you know that the doctors writing about vaccine
2360 safety are <span class="emphasis"><em>not</em></span> an aberration.
2361 </p><p>
2362 I’m 100% certain that vaccinating is safe and effective, but I’m also at
2363 something of a loss to explain exactly, <span class="emphasis"><em>precisely,</em></span> why
2364 I believe this, given all the corruption I know about and the many times the
2365 stamp of certainty has turned out to be a parochial lie told to further
2366 enrich the super rich.
2367 </p><p>
2368 Fake news — conspiracy theories, racist ideologies, scientific denialism —
2369 has always been with us. What’s changed today is not the mix of ideas in the
2370 public discourse but the popularity of the worst ideas in that
2371 mix. Conspiracy and denial have skyrocketed in lockstep with the growth of
2372 Big Inequality, which has also tracked the rise of Big Tech and Big Pharma
2373 and Big Wrestling and Big Car and Big Movie Theater and Big Everything Else.
2374 </p><p>
2375 No one can say for certain why this has happened, but the two dominant camps
2376 are idealism (the belief that the people who argue for these conspiracies
2377 have gotten better at explaining them, maybe with the help of
2378 machine-learning tools) or materialism (the ideas have become more
2379 attractive because of material conditions in the world).
2380 </p><p>
2381 I’m a materialist. I’ve been exposed to the arguments of conspiracy
2382 theorists all my life, and I have not experienced any qualitative leap in
2383 the quality of those arguments.
2384 </p><p>
2385 The major difference is in the world, not the arguments. In a time where
2386 actual conspiracies are commonplace, conspiracy theories acquire a ring of
2387 plausibility.
2388 </p><p>
2389 We have always had disagreements about what’s true, but today, we have a
2390 disagreement over how we know whether something is true. This is an
2391 epistemological crisis, not a crisis over belief. It’s a crisis over the
2392 credibility of our truth-seeking exercises, from scientific journals (in an
2393 era where the biggest journal publishers have been caught producing
2394 pay-to-play journals for junk science) to regulations (in an era where
2395 regulators are routinely cycling in and out of business) to education (in an
2396 era where universities are dependent on corporate donations to keep their
2397 lights on).
2398 </p><p>
2399 Targeting — surveillance capitalism — makes it easier to find people who are
2400 undergoing this epistemological crisis, but it doesn’t create the
2401 crisis. For that, you need to look to corruption.
2402 </p><p>
2403 And, conveniently enough, it’s corruption that allows surveillance
2404 capitalism to grow by dismantling monopoly protections, by permitting
2405 reckless collection and retention of personal data, by allowing ads to be
2406 targeted in secret, and by foreclosing on the possibility of going somewhere
2407 else where you might continue to enjoy your friends without subjecting
2408 yourself to commercial surveillance.
2409 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="tech-is-different"></a>Tech is different</h2></div></div></div><p>
2410 I reject both iterations of technological exceptionalism. I reject the idea
2411 that tech is uniquely terrible and led by people who are greedier or worse
2412 than the leaders of other industries, and I reject the idea that tech is so
2413 good — or so intrinsically prone to concentration — that it can’t be blamed
2414 for its present-day monopolistic status.
2415 </p><p>
2416 I think tech is just another industry, albeit one that grew up in the
2417 absence of real monopoly constraints. It may have been first, but it isn’t
2418 the worst nor will it be the last.
2419 </p><p>
2420 But there’s one way in which I <span class="emphasis"><em>am</em></span> a tech
2421 exceptionalist. I believe that online tools are the key to overcoming
2422 problems that are much more urgent than tech monopolization: climate change,
2423 inequality, misogyny, and discrimination on the basis of race, gender
2424 identity, and other factors. The internet is how we will recruit people to
2425 fight those fights, and how we will coordinate their labor. Tech is not a
2426 substitute for democratic accountability, the rule of law, fairness, or
2427 stability — but it’s a means to achieve these things.
2428 </p><p>
2429 The hard problem of our species is coordination. Everything from climate
2430 change to social change to running a business to making a family work can be
2431 viewed as a collective action problem.
2432 </p><p>
2433 The internet makes it easier than at any time before to find people who want
2434 to work on a project with you — hence the success of free and open-source
2435 software, crowdfunding, and racist terror groups — and easier than ever to
2436 coordinate the work you do.
2437 </p><p>
2438 The internet and the computers we connect to it also possess an exceptional
2439 quality: general-purposeness. The internet is designed to allow any two
2440 parties to communicate any data, using any protocol, without permission from
2441 anyone else. The only production design we have for computers is the
2442 general-purpose, <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Turing complete</span> »</span> computer that can run every
2443 program we can express in symbolic logic.
2444 </p><p>
2445 This means that every time someone with a special communications need
2446 invests in infrastructure and techniques to make the internet faster,
2447 cheaper, and more robust, this benefit redounds to everyone else who is
2448 using the internet to communicate. And this also means that every time
2449 someone with a special computing need invests to make computers faster,
2450 cheaper, and more robust, every other computing application is a potential
2451 beneficiary of this work.
2452 </p><p>
2453 For these reasons, every type of communication is gradually absorbed into
2454 the internet, and every type of device — from airplanes to pacemakers —
2455 eventually becomes a computer in a fancy case.
2456 </p><p>
2457 While these considerations don’t preclude regulating networks and computers,
2458 they do call for gravitas and caution when doing so because changes to
2459 regulatory frameworks could ripple out to have unintended consequences in
2460 many, many other domains.
2461 </p><p>
2462 The upshot of this is that our best hope of solving the big coordination
2463 problems — climate change, inequality, etc. — is with free, fair, and open
2464 tech. Our best hope of keeping tech free, fair, and open is to exercise
2465 caution in how we regulate tech and to attend closely to the ways in which
2466 interventions to solve one problem might create problems in other domains.
2467 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="ownership-of-facts"></a>Ownership of facts</h2></div></div></div><p>
2468 Big Tech has a funny relationship with information. When you’re generating
2469 information — anything from the location data streaming off your mobile
2470 device to the private messages you send to friends on a social network — it
2471 claims the rights to make unlimited use of that data.
2472 </p><p>
2473 But when you have the audacity to turn the tables — to use a tool that
2474 blocks ads or slurps your waiting updates out of a social network and puts
2475 them in another app that lets you set your own priorities and suggestions or
2476 crawls their system to allow you to start a rival business — they claim that
2477 you’re stealing from them.
2478 </p><p>
2479 The thing is, information is a very bad fit for any kind of private property
2480 regime. Property rights are useful for establishing markets that can lead to
2481 the effective development of fallow assets. These markets depend on clear
2482 titles to ensure that the things being bought and sold in them can, in fact,
2483 be bought and sold.
2484 </p><p>
2485 Information rarely has such a clear title. Take phone numbers: There’s
2486 clearly something going wrong when Facebook slurps up millions of users’
2487 address books and uses the phone numbers it finds in them to plot out social
2488 graphs and fill in missing information about other users.
2489 </p><p>
2490 But the phone numbers Facebook nonconsensually acquires in this transaction
2491 are not the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">property</span> »</span> of the users they’re taken from nor do
2492 they belong to the people whose phones ring when you dial those numbers. The
2493 numbers are mere integers, 10 digits in the U.S. and Canada, and they
2494 appear in millions of places, including somewhere deep in pi as well as
2495 numerous other contexts. Giving people ownership titles to integers is an
2496 obviously terrible idea.
2497 </p><p>
2498 Likewise for the facts that Facebook and other commercial surveillance
2499 operators acquire about us, like that we are the children of our parents or
2500 the parents to our children or that we had a conversation with someone else
2501 or went to a public place. These data points can’t be property in the sense
2502 that your house or your shirt is your property because the title to them is
2503 intrinsically muddy: Does your mom own the fact that she is your mother? Do
2504 you? Do both of you? What about your dad — does he own this fact too, or
2505 does he have to license the fact from you (or your mom or both of you) in
2506 order to use this fact? What about the hundreds or thousands of other people
2507 who know these facts?
2508 </p><p>
2509 If you go to a Black Lives Matter demonstration, do the other demonstrators
2510 need your permission to post their photos from the event? The online fights
2511 over <a class="ulink" href="https://www.wired.com/story/how-to-take-photos-at-protests/" target="_top">when and
2512 how to post photos from demonstrations</a> reveal a nuanced, complex
2513 issue that cannot be easily hand-waved away by giving one party a property
2514 right that everyone else in the mix has to respect.
2515 </p><p>
2516 The fact that information isn’t a good fit with property and markets doesn’t
2517 mean that it’s not valuable. Babies aren’t property, but they’re inarguably
2518 valuable. In fact, we have a whole set of rules just for babies as well as a
2519 subset of those rules that apply to humans more generally. Someone who
2520 argues that babies won’t be truly valuable until they can be bought and sold
2521 like loaves of bread would be instantly and rightfully condemned as a
2522 monster.
2523 </p><p>
2524 It’s tempting to reach for the property hammer when Big Tech treats your
2525 information like a nail — not least because Big Tech are such prolific
2526 abusers of property hammers when it comes to <span class="emphasis"><em>their</em></span>
2527 information. But this is a mistake. If we allow markets to dictate the use
2528 of our information, then we’ll find that we’re sellers in a buyers’ market
2529 where the Big Tech monopolies set a price for our data that is so low as to
2530 be insignificant or, more likely, set at a nonnegotiable price of zero in a
2531 click-through agreement that you don’t have the opportunity to modify.
2532 </p><p>
2533 Meanwhile, establishing property rights over information will create
2534 insurmountable barriers to independent data processing. Imagine that we
2535 require a license to be negotiated when a translated document is compared
2536 with its original, something Google has done and continues to do billions of
2537 times to train its automated language translation tools. Google can afford
2538 this, but independent third parties cannot. Google can staff a clearances
2539 department to negotiate one-time payments to the likes of the EU (one of the
2540 major repositories of translated documents) while independent watchdogs
2541 wanting to verify that the translations are well-prepared, or to root out
2542 bias in translations, will find themselves needing a staffed-up legal
2543 department and millions for licenses before they can even get started.
2544 </p><p>
2545 The same goes for things like search indexes of the web or photos of
2546 peoples’ houses, which have become contentious thanks to Google’s Street
2547 View project. Whatever problems may exist with Google’s photographing of
2548 street scenes, resolving them by letting people decide who can take pictures
2549 of the facades of their homes from a public street will surely create even
2550 worse ones. Think of how street photography is important for newsgathering —
2551 including informal newsgathering, like photographing abuses of authority —
2552 and how being able to document housing and street life are important for
2553 contesting eminent domain, advocating for social aid, reporting planning and
2554 zoning violations, documenting discriminatory and unequal living conditions,
2555 and more.
2556 </p><p>
2557 The ownership of facts is antithetical to many kinds of human progress. It’s
2558 hard to imagine a rule that limits Big Tech’s exploitation of our collective
2559 labors without inadvertently banning people from gathering data on online
2560 harassment or compiling indexes of changes in language or simply
2561 investigating how the platforms are shaping our discourse — all of which
2562 require scraping data that other people have created and subjecting it to
2563 scrutiny and analysis.
2564 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="persuasion-works-slowly"></a>Persuasion works… slowly</h2></div></div></div><p>
2565 The platforms may oversell their ability to persuade people, but obviously,
2566 persuasion works sometimes. Whether it’s the private realm that LGBTQ people
2567 used to recruit allies and normalize sexual diversity or the decadeslong
2568 project to convince people that markets are the only efficient way to solve
2569 complicated resource allocation problems, it’s clear that our societal
2570 attitudes <span class="emphasis"><em>can</em></span> change.
2571 </p><p>
2572 The project of shifting societal attitudes is a game of inches and
2573 years. For centuries, svengalis have purported to be able to accelerate this
2574 process, but even the most brutal forms of propaganda have struggled to make
2575 permanent changes. Joseph Goebbels was able to subject Germans to daily,
2576 mandatory, hourslong radio broadcasts, to round up and torture and murder
2577 dissidents, and to seize full control over their children’s education while
2578 banning any literature, broadcasts, or films that did not comport with his
2579 worldview.
2580 </p><p>
2581 Yet, after 12 years of terror, once the war ended, Nazi ideology was largely
2582 discredited in both East and West Germany, and a program of national truth
2583 and reconciliation was put in its place. Racism and authoritarianism were
2584 never fully abolished in Germany, but neither were the majority of Germans
2585 irrevocably convinced of Nazism — and the rise of racist authoritarianism in
2586 Germany today tells us that the liberal attitudes that replaced Nazism were
2587 no more permanent than Nazism itself.
2588 </p><p>
2589 Racism and authoritarianism have also always been with us. Anyone who’s
2590 reviewed the kind of messages and arguments that racists put forward today
2591 would be hard-pressed to say that they have gotten better at presenting
2592 their ideas. The same pseudoscience, appeals to fear, and circular logic
2593 that racists presented in the 1980s, when the cause of white supremacy was
2594 on the wane, are to be found in the communications of leading white
2595 nationalists today.
2596 </p><p>
2597 If racists haven’t gotten more convincing in the past decade, then how is it
2598 that more people were convinced to be openly racist at that time? I believe
2599 that the answer lies in the material world, not the world of ideas. The
2600 ideas haven’t gotten more convincing, but people have become more
2601 afraid. Afraid that the state can’t be trusted to act as an honest broker in
2602 life-or-death decisions, from those regarding the management of the economy
2603 to the regulation of painkillers to the rules for handling private
2604 information. Afraid that the world has become a game of musical chairs in
2605 which the chairs are being taken away at a never-before-seen rate. Afraid
2606 that justice for others will come at their expense. Monopolism isn’t the
2607 cause of these fears, but the inequality and material desperation and policy
2608 malpractice that monopolism contributes to is a significant contributor to
2609 these conditions. Inequality creates the conditions for both conspiracies
2610 and violent racist ideologies, and then surveillance capitalism lets
2611 opportunists target the fearful and the conspiracy-minded.
2612 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="paying-wont-help"></a>Paying won’t help</h2></div></div></div><p>
2613 As the old saw goes, <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">If you’re not paying for the product, you’re the
2614 product.</span> »</span>
2615 </p><p>
2616 It’s a commonplace belief today that the advent of free, ad-supported media
2617 was the original sin of surveillance capitalism. The reasoning is that the
2618 companies that charged for access couldn’t <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">compete with free</span> »</span>
2619 and so they were driven out of business. Their ad-supported competitors,
2620 meanwhile, declared open season on their users’ data in a bid to improve
2621 their ad targeting and make more money and then resorted to the most
2622 sensationalist tactics to generate clicks on those ads. If only we’d pay for
2623 media again, we’d have a better, more responsible, more sober discourse that
2624 would be better for democracy.
2625 </p><p>
2626 But the degradation of news products long precedes the advent of
2627 ad-supported online news. Long before newspapers were online, lax antitrust
2628 enforcement had opened the door for unprecedented waves of consolidation and
2629 roll-ups in newsrooms. Rival newspapers were merged, reporters and ad sales
2630 staff were laid off, physical plants were sold and leased back, leaving the
2631 companies loaded up with debt through leveraged buyouts and subsequent
2632 profit-taking by the new owners. In other words, it wasn’t merely shifts in
2633 the classified advertising market, which was long held to be the primary
2634 driver in the decline of the traditional newsroom, that made news companies
2635 unable to adapt to the internet — it was monopolism.
2636 </p><p>
2637 Then, as news companies <span class="emphasis"><em>did</em></span> come online, the ad
2638 revenues they commanded dropped even as the number of internet users (and
2639 thus potential online readers) increased. That shift was a function of
2640 consolidation in the ad sales market, with Google and Facebook emerging as
2641 duopolists who made more money every year from advertising while paying less
2642 and less of it to the publishers whose work the ads appeared
2643 alongside. Monopolism created a buyer’s market for ad inventory with
2644 Facebook and Google acting as gatekeepers.
2645 </p><p>
2646 Paid services continue to exist alongside free ones, and often it is these
2647 paid services — anxious to prevent people from bypassing their paywalls or
2648 sharing paid media with freeloaders — that exert the most control over their
2649 customers. Apple’s iTunes and App Stores are paid services, but to maximize
2650 their profitability, Apple has to lock its platforms so that third parties
2651 can’t make compatible software without permission. These locks allow the
2652 company to exercise both editorial control (enabling it to exclude <a class="ulink" href="https://ncac.org/news/blog/does-apples-strict-app-store-content-policy-limit-freedom-of-expression" target="_top">controversial
2653 political material</a>) and technological control, including control
2654 over who can repair the devices it makes. If we’re worried that ad-supported
2655 products deprive people of their right to self-determination by using
2656 persuasion techniques to nudge their purchase decisions a few degrees in one
2657 direction or the other, then the near-total control a single company holds
2658 over the decision of who gets to sell you software, parts, and service for
2659 your iPhone should have us very worried indeed.
2660 </p><p>
2661 We shouldn’t just be concerned about payment and control: The idea that
2662 paying will improve discourse is also dangerously wrong. The poor success
2663 rate of targeted advertising means that the platforms have to incentivize
2664 you to <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">engage</span> »</span> with posts at extremely high levels to generate
2665 enough pageviews to safeguard their profits. As discussed earlier, to
2666 increase engagement, platforms like Facebook use machine learning to guess
2667 which messages will be most inflammatory and make a point of shoving those
2668 into your eyeballs at every turn so that you will hate-click and argue with
2669 people.
2670 </p><p>
2671 Perhaps paying would fix this, the reasoning goes. If platforms could be
2672 economically viable even if you stopped clicking on them once your
2673 intellectual and social curiosity had been slaked, then they would have no
2674 reason to algorithmically enrage you to get more clicks out of you, right?
2675 </p><p>
2676 There may be something to that argument, but it still ignores the wider
2677 economic and political context of the platforms and the world that allowed
2678 them to grow so dominant.
2679 </p><p>
2680 Platforms are world-spanning and all-encompassing because they are
2681 monopolies, and they are monopolies because we have gutted our most
2682 important and reliable anti-monopoly rules. Antitrust was neutered as a key
2683 part of the project to make the wealthy wealthier, and that project has
2684 worked. The vast majority of people on Earth have a negative net worth, and
2685 even the dwindling middle class is in a precarious state, undersaved for
2686 retirement, underinsured for medical disasters, and undersecured against
2687 climate and technology shocks.
2688 </p><p>
2689 In this wildly unequal world, paying doesn’t improve the discourse; it
2690 simply prices discourse out of the range of the majority of people. Paying
2691 for the product is dandy, if you can afford it.
2692 </p><p>
2693 If you think today’s filter bubbles are a problem for our discourse, imagine
2694 what they’d be like if rich people inhabited free-flowing Athenian
2695 marketplaces of ideas where you have to pay for admission while everyone
2696 else lives in online spaces that are subsidized by wealthy benefactors who
2697 relish the chance to establish conversational spaces where the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">house
2698 rules</span> »</span> forbid questioning the status quo. That is, imagine if the
2699 rich seceded from Facebook, and then, instead of running ads that made money
2700 for shareholders, Facebook became a billionaire’s vanity project that also
2701 happened to ensure that nobody talked about whether it was fair that only
2702 billionaires could afford to hang out in the rarified corners of the
2703 internet.
2704 </p><p>
2705 Behind the idea of paying for access is a belief that free markets will
2706 address Big Tech’s dysfunction. After all, to the extent that people have a
2707 view of surveillance at all, it is generally an unfavorable one, and the
2708 longer and more thoroughly one is surveilled, the less one tends to like
2709 it. Same goes for lock-in: If HP’s ink or Apple’s App Store were really
2710 obviously fantastic, they wouldn’t need technical measures to prevent users
2711 from choosing a rival’s product. The only reason these technical
2712 countermeasures exist is that the companies don’t believe their customers
2713 would <span class="emphasis"><em>voluntarily</em></span> submit to their terms, and they want
2714 to deprive them of the choice to take their business elsewhere.
2715 </p><p>
2716 Advocates for markets laud their ability to aggregate the diffused knowledge
2717 of buyers and sellers across a whole society through demand signals, price
2718 signals, and so on. The argument for surveillance capitalism being a
2719 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism</span> »</span> is that machine-learning-driven persuasion
2720 techniques distort decision-making by consumers, leading to incorrect
2721 signals — consumers don’t buy what they prefer, they buy what they’re
2722 tricked into preferring. It follows that the monopolistic practices of
2723 lock-in, which do far more to constrain consumers’ free choices, are even
2724 more of a <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">rogue capitalism.</span> »</span>
2725 </p><p>
2726 The profitability of any business is constrained by the possibility that its
2727 customers will take their business elsewhere. Both surveillance and lock-in
2728 are anti-features that no customer wants. But monopolies can capture their
2729 regulators, crush their competitors, insert themselves into their customers’
2730 lives, and corral people into <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">choosing</span> »</span> their services
2731 regardless of whether they want them — it’s fine to be terrible when there
2732 is no alternative.
2733 </p><p>
2734 Ultimately, surveillance and lock-in are both simply business strategies
2735 that monopolists can choose. Surveillance companies like Google are
2736 perfectly capable of deploying lock-in technologies — just look at the
2737 onerous Android licensing terms that require device-makers to bundle in
2738 Google’s suite of applications. And lock-in companies like Apple are
2739 perfectly capable of subjecting their users to surveillance if it means
2740 keeping the Chinese government happy and preserving ongoing access to
2741 Chinese markets. Monopolies may be made up of good, ethical people, but as
2742 institutions, they are not your friend — they will do whatever they can get
2743 away with to maximize their profits, and the more monopolistic they are, the
2744 more they <span class="emphasis"><em>can</em></span> get away with.
2745 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="an-ecology-moment-for-trustbusting"></a>An <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">ecology</span> »</span> moment for trustbusting</h2></div></div></div><p>
2746 If we’re going to break Big Tech’s death grip on our digital lives, we’re
2747 going to have to fight monopolies. That may sound pretty mundane and
2748 old-fashioned, something out of the New Deal era, while ending the use of
2749 automated behavioral modification feels like the plotline of a really cool
2750 cyberpunk novel.
2751 </p><p>
2752 Meanwhile, breaking up monopolies is something we seem to have forgotten how
2753 to do. There is a bipartisan, trans-Atlantic consensus that breaking up
2754 companies is a fool’s errand at best — liable to mire your federal
2755 prosecutors in decades of litigation — and counterproductive at worst,
2756 eroding the <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">consumer benefits</span> »</span> of large companies with massive
2757 efficiencies of scale.
2758 </p><p>
2759 But trustbusters once strode the nation, brandishing law books, terrorizing
2760 robber barons, and shattering the illusion of monopolies’ all-powerful grip
2761 on our society. The trustbusting era could not begin until we found the
2762 political will — until the people convinced politicians they’d have their
2763 backs when they went up against the richest, most powerful men in the world.
2764 </p><p>
2765 Could we find that political will again?
2766 </p><p>
2767 Copyright scholar James Boyle has described how the term
2768 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">ecology</span> »</span> marked a turning point in environmental
2769 activism. Prior to the adoption of this term, people who wanted to preserve
2770 whale populations didn’t necessarily see themselves as fighting the same
2771 battle as people who wanted to protect the ozone layer or fight freshwater
2772 pollution or beat back smog or acid rain.
2773 </p><p>
2774 But the term <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">ecology</span> »</span> welded these disparate causes together
2775 into a single movement, and the members of this movement found solidarity
2776 with one another. The people who cared about smog signed petitions
2777 circulated by the people who wanted to end whaling, and the anti-whalers
2778 marched alongside the people demanding action on acid rain. This uniting
2779 behind a common cause completely changed the dynamics of environmentalism,
2780 setting the stage for today’s climate activism and the sense that preserving
2781 the habitability of the planet Earth is a shared duty among all people.
2782 </p><p>
2783 I believe we are on the verge of a new <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">ecology</span> »</span> moment
2784 dedicated to combating monopolies. After all, tech isn’t the only
2785 concentrated industry nor is it even the <span class="emphasis"><em>most</em></span>
2786 concentrated of industries.
2787 </p><p>
2788 You can find partisans for trustbusting in every sector of the
2789 economy. Everywhere you look, you can find people who’ve been wronged by
2790 monopolists who’ve trashed their finances, their health, their privacy,
2791 their educations, and the lives of people they love. Those people have the
2792 same cause as the people who want to break up Big Tech and the same
2793 enemies. When most of the world’s wealth is in the hands of a very few, it
2794 follows that nearly every large company will have overlapping shareholders.
2795 </p><p>
2796 That’s the good news: With a little bit of work and a little bit of
2797 coalition building, we have more than enough political will to break up Big
2798 Tech and every other concentrated industry besides. First we take Facebook,
2799 then we take AT&amp;T/WarnerMedia.
2800 </p><p>
2801 But here’s the bad news: Much of what we’re doing to tame Big Tech
2802 <span class="emphasis"><em>instead</em></span> of breaking up the big companies also
2803 forecloses on the possibility of breaking them up later.
2804 </p><p>
2805 Big Tech’s concentration currently means that their inaction on harassment,
2806 for example, leaves users with an impossible choice: absent themselves from
2807 public discourse by, say, quitting Twitter or endure vile, constant
2808 abuse. Big Tech’s over-collection and over-retention of data results in
2809 horrific identity theft. And their inaction on extremist recruitment means
2810 that white supremacists who livestream their shooting rampages can reach an
2811 audience of billions. The combination of tech concentration and media
2812 concentration means that artists’ incomes are falling even as the revenue
2813 generated by their creations are increasing.
2814 </p><p>
2815 Yet governments confronting all of these problems all inevitably converge on
2816 the same solution: deputize the Big Tech giants to police their users and
2817 render them liable for their users’ bad actions. The drive to force Big Tech
2818 to use automated filters to block everything from copyright infringement to
2819 sex-trafficking to violent extremism means that tech companies will have to
2820 allocate hundreds of millions to run these compliance systems.
2821 </p><p>
2822 These rules — the EU’s new Directive on Copyright, Australia’s new terror
2823 regulation, America’s FOSTA/SESTA sex-trafficking law and more — are not
2824 just death warrants for small, upstart competitors that might challenge Big
2825 Tech’s dominance but who lack the deep pockets of established incumbents to
2826 pay for all these automated systems. Worse still, these rules put a floor
2827 under how small we can hope to make Big Tech.
2828 </p><p>
2829 That’s because any move to break up Big Tech and cut it down to size will
2830 have to cope with the hard limit of not making these companies so small that
2831 they can no longer afford to perform these duties — and it’s
2832 <span class="emphasis"><em>expensive</em></span> to invest in those automated filters and
2833 outsource content moderation. It’s already going to be hard to unwind these
2834 deeply concentrated, chimeric behemoths that have been welded together in
2835 the pursuit of monopoly profits. Doing so while simultaneously finding some
2836 way to fill the regulatory void that will be left behind if these
2837 self-policing rulers were forced to suddenly abdicate will be much, much
2838 harder.
2839 </p><p>
2840 Allowing the platforms to grow to their present size has given them a
2841 dominance that is nearly insurmountable — deputizing them with public duties
2842 to redress the pathologies created by their size makes it virtually
2843 impossible to reduce that size. Lather, rinse, repeat: If the platforms
2844 don’t get smaller, they will get larger, and as they get larger, they will
2845 create more problems, which will give rise to more public duties for the
2846 companies, which will make them bigger still.
2847 </p><p>
2848 We can work to fix the internet by breaking up Big Tech and depriving them
2849 of monopoly profits, or we can work to fix Big Tech by making them spend
2850 their monopoly profits on governance. But we can’t do both. We have to
2851 choose between a vibrant, open internet or a dominated, monopolized internet
2852 commanded by Big Tech giants that we struggle with constantly to get them to
2853 behave themselves.
2854 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="make-big-tech-small-again"></a>Make Big Tech small again</h2></div></div></div><p>
2855 Trustbusting is hard. Breaking big companies into smaller ones is expensive
2856 and time-consuming. So time-consuming that by the time you’re done, the
2857 world has often moved on and rendered years of litigation irrelevant. From
2858 1969 to 1982, the U.S. government pursued an antitrust case against IBM over
2859 its dominance of mainframe computing — but the case collapsed in 1982
2860 because mainframes were being speedily replaced by PCs.
2861 </p><div class="blockquote"><blockquote class="blockquote"><p>
2862 A future U.S. president could simply direct their attorney general to
2863 enforce the law as it was written.
2864 </p></blockquote></div><p>
2865 It’s far easier to prevent concentration than to fix it, and reinstating the
2866 traditional contours of U.S. antitrust enforcement will, at the very least,
2867 prevent further concentration. That means bans on mergers between large
2868 companies, on big companies acquiring nascent competitors, and on platform
2869 companies competing directly with the companies that rely on the platforms.
2870 </p><p>
2871 These powers are all in the plain language of U.S. antitrust laws, so in
2872 theory, a future U.S. president could simply direct their attorney general
2873 to enforce the law as it was written. But after decades of judicial
2874 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">education</span> »</span> in the benefits of monopolies, after multiple
2875 administrations that have packed the federal courts with lifetime-appointed
2876 monopoly cheerleaders, it’s not clear that mere administrative action would
2877 do the trick.
2878 </p><p>
2879 If the courts frustrate the Justice Department and the president, the next
2880 stop would be Congress, which could eliminate any doubt about how antitrust
2881 law should be enforced in the U.S. by passing new laws that boil down to
2882 saying, <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">Knock it off. We all know what the Sherman Act says. Robert
2883 Bork was a deranged fantasist. For avoidance of doubt, <span class="emphasis"><em>fuck that
2884 guy</em></span>.</span> »</span> In other words, the problem with monopolies is
2885 <span class="emphasis"><em>monopolism</em></span> — the concentration of power into too few
2886 hands, which erodes our right to self-determination. If there is a monopoly,
2887 the law wants it gone, period. Sure, get rid of monopolies that create
2888 <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">consumer harm</span> »</span> in the form of higher prices, but also,
2889 <span class="emphasis"><em>get rid of other monopolies, too</em></span>.
2890 </p><p>
2891 But this only prevents things from getting worse. To help them get better,
2892 we will have to build coalitions with other activists in the anti-monopoly
2893 ecology movement — a pluralism movement or a self-determination movement —
2894 and target existing monopolies in every industry for breakup and structural
2895 separation rules that prevent, for example, the giant eyewear monopolist
2896 Luxottica from dominating both the sale and the manufacture of spectacles.
2897 </p><p>
2898 In an important sense, it doesn’t matter which industry the breakups begin
2899 in. Once they start, shareholders in <span class="emphasis"><em>every</em></span> industry
2900 will start to eye their investments in monopolists skeptically. As
2901 trustbusters ride into town and start making lives miserable for
2902 monopolists, the debate around every corporate boardroom’s table will
2903 shift. People within corporations who’ve always felt uneasy about monopolism
2904 will gain a powerful new argument to fend off their evil rivals in the
2905 corporate hierarchy: <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">If we do it my way, we make less money; if we do
2906 it your way, a judge will fine us billions and expose us to ridicule and
2907 public disapprobation. So even though I get that it would be really cool to
2908 do that merger, lock out that competitor, or buy that little company and
2909 kill it before it can threaten it, we really shouldn’t — not if we don’t
2910 want to get tied to the DOJ’s bumper and get dragged up and down Trustbuster
2911 Road for the next 10 years.</span> »</span>
2912 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="goto-10"></a>20 GOTO 10</h2></div></div></div><p>
2913 Fixing Big Tech will require a lot of iteration. As cyber lawyer Lawrence
2914 Lessig wrote in his 1999 book, <span class="emphasis"><em>Code and Other Laws of
2915 Cyberspace</em></span>, our lives are regulated by four forces: law (what’s
2916 legal), code (what’s technologically possible), norms (what’s socially
2917 acceptable), and markets (what’s profitable).
2918 </p><p>
2919 If you could wave a wand and get Congress to pass a law that re-fanged the
2920 Sherman Act tomorrow, you could use the impending breakups to convince
2921 venture capitalists to fund competitors to Facebook, Google, Twitter, and
2922 Apple that would be waiting in the wings after they were cut down to size.
2923 </p><p>
2924 But getting Congress to act will require a massive normative shift, a mass
2925 movement of people who care about monopolies — and pulling them apart.
2926 </p><p>
2927 Getting people to care about monopolies will take technological
2928 interventions that help them to see what a world free from Big Tech might
2929 look like. Imagine if someone could make a beloved (but unauthorized)
2930 third-party Facebook or Twitter client that dampens the anxiety-producing
2931 algorithmic drumbeat and still lets you talk to your friends without being
2932 spied upon — something that made social media more sociable and less
2933 toxic. Now imagine that it gets shut down in a brutal legal battle. It’s
2934 always easier to convince people that something must be done to save a thing
2935 they love than it is to excite them about something that doesn’t even exist
2936 yet.
2937 </p><p>
2938 Neither tech nor law nor code nor markets are sufficient to reform Big
2939 Tech. But a profitable competitor to Big Tech could bankroll a legislative
2940 push; legal reform can embolden a toolsmith to make a better tool; the tool
2941 can create customers for a potential business who value the benefits of the
2942 internet but want them delivered without Big Tech; and that business can get
2943 funded and divert some of its profits to legal reform. 20 GOTO 10 (or
2944 lather, rinse, repeat). Do it again, but this time, get farther! After all,
2945 this time you’re starting with weaker Big Tech adversaries, a constituency
2946 that understands things can be better, Big Tech rivals who’ll help ensure
2947 their own future by bankrolling reform, and code that other programmers can
2948 build on to weaken Big Tech even further.
2949 </p><p>
2950 The surveillance capitalism hypothesis — that Big Tech’s products really
2951 work as well as they say they do and that’s why everything is so screwed up
2952 — is way too easy on surveillance and even easier on capitalism. Companies
2953 spy because they believe their own BS, and companies spy because governments
2954 let them, and companies spy because any advantage from spying is so
2955 short-lived and minor that they have to do more and more of it just to stay
2956 in place.
2957 </p><p>
2958 As to why things are so screwed up? Capitalism. Specifically, the monopolism
2959 that creates inequality and the inequality that creates monopolism. It’s a
2960 form of capitalism that rewards sociopaths who destroy the real economy to
2961 inflate the bottom line, and they get away with it for the same reason
2962 companies get away with spying: because our governments are in thrall to
2963 both the ideology that says monopolies are actually just fine and in thrall
2964 to the ideology that says that in a monopolistic world, you’d better not
2965 piss off the monopolists.
2966 </p><p>
2967 Surveillance doesn’t make capitalism rogue. Capitalism’s unchecked rule
2968 begets surveillance. Surveillance isn’t bad because it lets people
2969 manipulate us. It’s bad because it crushes our ability to be our authentic
2970 selves — and because it lets the rich and powerful figure out who might be
2971 thinking of building guillotines and what dirt they can use to discredit
2972 those embryonic guillotine-builders before they can even get to the
2973 lumberyard.
2974 </p></div><div class="sect1"><div class="titlepage"><div><div><h2 class="title" style="clear: both"><a name="up-and-through"></a>Up and through</h2></div></div></div><p>
2975 With all the problems of Big Tech, it’s tempting to imagine solving the
2976 problem by returning to a world without tech at all. Resist that temptation.
2977 </p><p>
2978 The only way out of our Big Tech problem is up and through. If our future is
2979 not reliant upon high tech, it will be because civilization has fallen. Big
2980 Tech wired together a planetary, species-wide nervous system that, with the
2981 proper reforms and course corrections, is capable of seeing us through the
2982 existential challenge of our species and planet. Now it’s up to us to seize
2983 the means of computation, putting that electronic nervous system under
2984 democratic, accountable control.
2985 </p><p>
2986 I am, secretly, despite what I have said earlier, a tech exceptionalist. Not
2987 in the sense of thinking that tech should be given a free pass to monopolize
2988 because it has <span class="quote">« <span class="quote">economies of scale</span> »</span> or some other nebulous
2989 feature. I’m a tech exceptionalist because I believe that getting tech right
2990 matters and that getting it wrong will be an unmitigated catastrophe — and
2991 doing it right can give us the power to work together to save our
2992 civilization, our species, and our planet.
2993 </p></div></div></body></html>