From: Petter Reinholdtsen Date: Wed, 30 Dec 2020 06:15:09 +0000 (+0100) Subject: Generate French draft. X-Git-Tag: nb-printed-2021-01-24~76 X-Git-Url: https://pere.pagekite.me/gitweb/text-destroy-surveillance.git/commitdiff_plain/ae9d39bfa79d7c529a06de9f7e2b37fd6d1f3d03?ds=inline Generate French draft. --- diff --git a/Makefile b/Makefile index 14005d1..db9f99e 100644 --- a/Makefile +++ b/Makefile @@ -1,6 +1,7 @@ SOURCE=how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism GENERATED = $(SOURCE).xml $(SOURCE).pdf $(SOURCE).html $(SOURCE).epub \ $(SOURCE).de.xml $(SOURCE).de.pdf $(SOURCE).de.html $(SOURCE).de.epub \ + $(SOURCE).fr.xml $(SOURCE).fr.pdf $(SOURCE).fr.html $(SOURCE).fr.epub \ $(SOURCE).nb.xml $(SOURCE).nb.pdf $(SOURCE).nb.html $(SOURCE).nb.epub \ $(SOURCE).pl.xml $(SOURCE).pl.pdf $(SOURCE).pl.html $(SOURCE).pl.epub @@ -41,6 +42,11 @@ $(SOURCE).de.xml: po/$(SOURCE).de.po $(SOURCE).xml $(SOURCE).de.pdf: $(SOURCE).de.xml Makefile pdf.xsl dblatex $(DBLATEX_OPTS) $(SOURCE).de.xml -o $@ +$(SOURCE).fr.xml: po/$(SOURCE).fr.po $(SOURCE).xml + po4a --translate-only $(SOURCE).fr.xml po4a.cfg +$(SOURCE).fr.pdf: $(SOURCE).fr.xml Makefile pdf.xsl + dblatex $(DBLATEX_OPTS) $(SOURCE).fr.xml -o $@ + $(SOURCE).nb.xml: po/$(SOURCE).nb.po $(SOURCE).xml po4a --translate-only $(SOURCE).nb.xml po4a.cfg $(SOURCE).nb.pdf: $(SOURCE).nb.xml Makefile pdf.xsl diff --git a/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.epub b/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.epub new file mode 100644 index 0000000..cc8c132 Binary files /dev/null and b/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.epub differ diff --git a/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.html b/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.html new file mode 100644 index 0000000..d967354 --- /dev/null +++ b/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.html @@ -0,0 +1,2991 @@ +How to Destroy Surveillance Capitalism

How to Destroy Surveillance Capitalism

Cory Doctorow

+ How to Destroy Surveillance Capitalism by Cory Doctorow. +

+ Published by Petter Reinholdtsen. +

+ ISBN 978-82-93828-XX-X (hard cover) +

+ ISBN 978-82-93828-XX-X (paperback) +

+ ISBN 978-82-93828-XX-X (ePub) +

+ This book is available for purchase from https://www.lulu.com/. +

+ If you find typos, error or have other corrections to the translated text, +please update on https://hosted.weblate.org/projects/rms-personal-data-safe/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism/nb_NO/. +

+ Creative Commons, Some rights reserved +

+ This book is licensed under a Creative Commons license. This license permits +any use of this work, so long as attribution is given and no derivatived +material is distributed. For more information about the license visit +https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nd/4.0/. +

Abstract

+ Our devices and services gather most of the data that the NSA mines for its +surveillance project. We pay for these devices and the services they connect +to, and then we painstakingly perform the data-entry tasks associated with +logging facts about our lives, opinions, and preferences. +

+ Thanks to Big Tech, Surveillance capitalism is everywhere. This is not +because it is really good at manipulating our behaviour, or the rogue abuse +of corporate power. It is the result of unchecked monopolism and the +abusive behavior it abets. It is the system working as intended and +expected. Cory Doctorow has written an extended critique of Shoshana +Zuboff's The Age of Surveillance Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at +the New Frontier of Power, with a non-magical analysis of the problem +leading to a different proposal for a solution. +


The net of a thousand lies

+ The most surprising thing about the rebirth of flat Earthers in the 21st +century is just how widespread the evidence against them is. You can +understand how, centuries ago, people who’d never gained a high-enough +vantage point from which to see the Earth’s curvature might come to the +commonsense belief that the flat-seeming Earth was, indeed, flat. +

+ But today, when elementary schools routinely dangle GoPro cameras from +balloons and loft them high enough to photograph the Earth’s curve — to say +nothing of the unexceptional sight of the curved Earth from an airplane +window — it takes a heroic effort to maintain the belief that the world is +flat. +

+ Likewise for white nationalism and eugenics: In an age where you can become +a computational genomics datapoint by swabbing your cheek and mailing it to +a gene-sequencing company along with a modest sum of money, “race +science” has never been easier to refute. +

+ We are living through a golden age of both readily available facts and +denial of those facts. Terrible ideas that have lingered on the fringes for +decades or even centuries have gone mainstream seemingly overnight. +

+ When an obscure idea gains currency, there are only two things that can +explain its ascendance: Either the person expressing that idea has gotten a +lot better at stating their case, or the proposition has become harder to +deny in the face of mounting evidence. In other words, if we want people to +take climate change seriously, we can get a bunch of Greta Thunbergs to make +eloquent, passionate arguments from podiums, winning our hearts and minds, +or we can wait for flood, fire, broiling sun, and pandemics to make the case +for us. In practice, we’ll probably have to do some of both: The more we’re +boiling and burning and drowning and wasting away, the easier it will be for +the Greta Thunbergs of the world to convince us. +

+ The arguments for ridiculous beliefs in odious conspiracies like +anti-vaccination, climate denial, a flat Earth, and eugenics are no better +than they were a generation ago. Indeed, they’re worse because they are +being pitched to people who have at least a background awareness of the +refuting facts. +

+ Anti-vax has been around since the first vaccines, but the early +anti-vaxxers were pitching people who were less equipped to understand even +the most basic ideas from microbiology, and moreover, those people had not +witnessed the extermination of mass-murdering diseases like polio, smallpox, +and measles. Today’s anti-vaxxers are no more eloquent than their forebears, +and they have a much harder job. +

+ So can these far-fetched conspiracy theorists really be succeeding on the +basis of superior arguments? +

+ Some people think so. Today, there is a widespread belief that machine +learning and commercial surveillance can turn even the most fumble-tongued +conspiracy theorist into a svengali who can warp your perceptions and win +your belief by locating vulnerable people and then pitching them with +A.I.-refined arguments that bypass their rational faculties and turn +everyday people into flat Earthers, anti-vaxxers, or even Nazis. When the +RAND Corporation blames +Facebook for “radicalization” and when Facebook’s role +in spreading coronavirus misinformation is blamed on +its algorithm, the implicit message is that machine learning and +surveillance are causing the changes in our consensus about what’s true. +

+ After all, in a world where sprawling and incoherent conspiracy theories +like Pizzagate and its successor, QAnon, have widespread followings, +something must be afoot. +

+ But what if there’s another explanation? What if it’s the material +circumstances, and not the arguments, that are making the difference for +these conspiracy pitchmen? What if the trauma of living through +real conspiracies all around us — conspiracies among +wealthy people, their lobbyists, and lawmakers to bury inconvenient facts +and evidence of wrongdoing (these conspiracies are commonly known as +“corruption”) — is making people vulnerable to conspiracy +theories? +

+ If it’s trauma and not contagion — material conditions and not ideology — +that is making the difference today and enabling a rise of repulsive +misinformation in the face of easily observed facts, that doesn’t mean our +computer networks are blameless. They’re still doing the heavy work of +locating vulnerable people and guiding them through a series of +ever-more-extreme ideas and communities. +

+ Belief in conspiracy is a raging fire that has done real damage and poses +real danger to our planet and species, from epidemics kicked off by vaccine +denial to genocides kicked +off by racist conspiracies to planetary meltdown caused by +denial-inspired climate inaction. Our world is on fire, and so we have to +put the fires out — to figure out how to help people see the truth of the +world through the conspiracies they’ve been confused by. +

+ But firefighting is reactive. We need fire +prevention. We need to strike at the traumatic material +conditions that make people vulnerable to the contagion of conspiracy. Here, +too, tech has a role to play. +

+ There’s no shortage of proposals to address this. From the EU’s Terrorist Content Regulation, +which requires platforms to police and remove “extremist” +content, to the U.S. proposals to force +tech companies to spy on their users and hold them liable for their +users’ bad speech, there’s a lot of energy to force tech companies +to solve the problems they created. +

+ There’s a critical piece missing from the debate, though. All these +solutions assume that tech companies are a fixture, that their dominance +over the internet is a permanent fact. Proposals to replace Big Tech with a +more diffused, pluralistic internet are nowhere to be found. Worse: The +“solutions” on the table today require Big +Tech to stay big because only the very largest companies can afford to +implement the systems these laws demand. +

+ Figuring out what we want our tech to look like is crucial if we’re going to +get out of this mess. Today, we’re at a crossroads where we’re trying to +figure out if we want to fix the Big Tech companies that dominate our +internet or if we want to fix the internet itself by unshackling it from Big +Tech’s stranglehold. We can’t do both, so we have to choose. +

+ I want us to choose wisely. Taming Big Tech is integral to fixing the +Internet, and for that, we need digital rights activism. +

Digital rights activism, a quarter-century on

+ Digital rights activism is more than 30 years old now. The Electronic +Frontier Foundation turned 30 this year; the Free Software Foundation +launched in 1985. For most of the history of the movement, the most +prominent criticism leveled against it was that it was irrelevant: The real +activist causes were real-world causes (think of the skepticism when Finland +declared broadband a human right in 2010), and real-world activism +was shoe-leather activism (think of Malcolm Gladwell’s contempt +for “clicktivism”). But as tech has grown more central +to our daily lives, these accusations of irrelevance have given way first to +accusations of insincerity (“You only care about tech because you’re +shilling +for tech companies”) to accusations of negligence (“Why +didn’t you foresee that tech could be such a destructive force?”). +But digital rights activism is right where it’s always been: looking out for +the humans in a world where tech is inexorably taking over. +

+ The latest version of this critique comes in the form of “surveillance +capitalism,” a term coined by business professor Shoshana Zuboff in +her long and influential 2019 book, The Age of Surveillance +Capitalism: The Fight for a Human Future at the New Frontier of +Power. Zuboff argues that “surveillance capitalism” +is a unique creature of the tech industry and that it is unlike any other +abusive commercial practice in history, one that is “constituted by +unexpected and often illegible mechanisms of extraction, commodification, +and control that effectively exile persons from their own behavior while +producing new markets of behavioral prediction and +modification. Surveillance capitalism challenges democratic norms and +departs in key ways from the centuries-long evolution of market +capitalism.” It is a new and deadly form of capitalism, a +“rogue capitalism,” and our lack of understanding of its unique +capabilities and dangers represents an existential, species-wide +threat. She’s right that capitalism today threatens our species, and she’s +right that tech poses unique challenges to our species and civilization, but +she’s really wrong about how tech is different and why it threatens our +species. +

+ What’s more, I think that her incorrect diagnosis will lead us down a path +that ends up making Big Tech stronger, not weaker. We need to take down Big +Tech, and to do that, we need to start by correctly identifying the problem. +

Tech exceptionalism, then and now

+ Early critics of the digital rights movement — perhaps best represented by +campaigning organizations like the Electronic Frontier Foundation, the Free +Software Foundation, Public Knowledge, and others that focused on preserving +and enhancing basic human rights in the digital realm — damned activists for +practicing “tech exceptionalism.” Around the turn of the +millennium, serious people ridiculed any claim that tech policy mattered in +the “real world.” Claims that tech rules had implications for +speech, association, privacy, search and seizure, and fundamental rights and +equities were treated as ridiculous, an elevation of the concerns of sad +nerds arguing about Star Trek on bulletin board systems +above the struggles of the Freedom Riders, Nelson Mandela, or the Warsaw +ghetto uprising. +

+ In the decades since, accusations of “tech exceptionalism” have +only sharpened as tech’s role in everyday life has expanded: Now that tech +has infiltrated every corner of our life and our online lives have been +monopolized by a handful of giants, defenders of digital freedoms are +accused of carrying water for Big Tech, providing cover for its +self-interested negligence (or worse, nefarious plots). +

+ From my perspective, the digital rights movement has remained stationary +while the rest of the world has moved. From the earliest days, the +movement’s concern was users and the toolsmiths who provided the code they +needed to realize their fundamental rights. Digital rights activists only +cared about companies to the extent that companies were acting to uphold +users’ rights (or, just as often, when companies were acting so foolishly +that they threatened to bring down new rules that would also make it harder +for good actors to help users). +

+ The “surveillance capitalism” critique recasts the digital +rights movement in a new light again: not as alarmists who overestimate the +importance of their shiny toys nor as shills for big tech but as serene +deck-chair rearrangers whose long-standing activism is a liability because +it makes them incapable of perceiving novel threats as they continue to +fight the last century’s tech battles. +

+ But tech exceptionalism is a sin no matter who practices it. +

Don’t believe the hype

+ You’ve probably heard that “if you’re not paying for the product, +you’re the product.” As we’ll see below, that’s true, if incomplete. +But what is absolutely true is that ad-driven Big +Tech’s customers are advertisers, and what companies like Google and +Facebook sell is their ability to convince you to buy +stuff. Big Tech’s product is persuasion. The services — social media, search +engines, maps, messaging, and more — are delivery systems for persuasion. +

+ The fear of surveillance capitalism starts from the (correct) presumption +that everything Big Tech says about itself is probably a lie. But the +surveillance capitalism critique makes an exception for the claims Big Tech +makes in its sales literature — the breathless hype in the pitches to +potential advertisers online and in ad-tech seminars about the efficacy of +its products: It assumes that Big Tech is as good at influencing us as they +claim they are when they’re selling influencing products to credulous +customers. That’s a mistake because sales literature is not a reliable +indicator of a product’s efficacy. +

+ Surveillance capitalism assumes that because advertisers buy a lot of what +Big Tech is selling, Big Tech must be selling something real. But Big Tech’s +massive sales could just as easily be the result of a popular delusion or +something even more pernicious: monopolistic control over our communications +and commerce. +

+ Being watched changes your behavior, and not for the better. It creates +risks for our social progress. Zuboff’s book features beautifully wrought +explanations of these phenomena. But Zuboff also claims that surveillance +literally robs us of our free will — that when our personal data is mixed +with machine learning, it creates a system of persuasion so devastating that +we are helpless before it. That is, Facebook uses an algorithm to analyze +the data it nonconsensually extracts from your daily life and uses it to +customize your feed in ways that get you to buy stuff. It is a mind-control +ray out of a 1950s comic book, wielded by mad scientists whose +supercomputers guarantee them perpetual and total world domination. +

What is persuasion?

+ To understand why you shouldn’t worry about mind-control rays — but why you +should worry about surveillance +and Big Tech — we must start by unpacking what we mean +by “persuasion.” +

+ Google, Facebook, and other surveillance capitalists promise their customers +(the advertisers) that if they use machine-learning tools trained on +unimaginably large data sets of nonconsensually harvested personal +information, they will be able to uncover ways to bypass the rational +faculties of the public and direct their behavior, creating a stream of +purchases, votes, and other desired outcomes. +

+ The impact of dominance far exceeds the impact of manipulation and should be +central to our analysis and any remedies we seek. +

+ But there’s little evidence that this is happening. Instead, the predictions +that surveillance capitalism delivers to its customers are much less +impressive. Rather than finding ways to bypass our rational faculties, +surveillance capitalists like Mark Zuckerberg mostly do one or more of three +things: +

1. Segmenting

+ If you’re selling diapers, you have better luck if you pitch them to people +in maternity wards. Not everyone who enters or leaves a maternity ward just +had a baby, and not everyone who just had a baby is in the market for +diapers. But having a baby is a really reliable correlate of being in the +market for diapers, and being in a maternity ward is highly correlated with +having a baby. Hence diaper ads around maternity wards (and even pitchmen +for baby products, who haunt maternity wards with baskets full of freebies). +

+ Surveillance capitalism is segmenting times a billion. Diaper vendors can go +way beyond people in maternity wards (though they can do that, too, with +things like location-based mobile ads). They can target you based on +whether you’re reading articles about child-rearing, diapers, or a host of +other subjects, and data mining can suggest unobvious keywords to advertise +against. They can target you based on the articles you’ve recently +read. They can target you based on what you’ve recently purchased. They can +target you based on whether you receive emails or private messages about +these subjects — or even if you speak aloud about them (though Facebook and +the like convincingly claim that’s not happening — yet). +

+ This is seriously creepy. +

+ But it’s not mind control. +

+ It doesn’t deprive you of your free will. It doesn’t trick you. +

+ Think of how surveillance capitalism works in politics. Surveillance +capitalist companies sell political operatives the power to locate people +who might be receptive to their pitch. Candidates campaigning on finance +industry corruption seek people struggling with debt; candidates campaigning +on xenophobia seek out racists. Political operatives have always targeted +their message whether their intentions were honorable or not: Union +organizers set up pitches at factory gates, and white supremacists hand out +fliers at John Birch Society meetings. +

+ But this is an inexact and thus wasteful practice. The union organizer can’t +know which worker to approach on the way out of the factory gates and may +waste their time on a covert John Birch Society member; the white +supremacist doesn’t know which of the Birchers are so delusional that making +it to a meeting is as much as they can manage and which ones might be +convinced to cross the country to carry a tiki torch through the streets of +Charlottesville, Virginia. +

+ Because targeting improves the yields on political pitches, it can +accelerate the pace of political upheaval by making it possible for everyone +who has secretly wished for the toppling of an autocrat — or just an 11-term +incumbent politician — to find everyone else who feels the same way at very +low cost. This has been critical to the rapid crystallization of recent +political movements including Black Lives Matter and Occupy Wall Street as +well as less savory players like the far-right white nationalist movements +that marched in Charlottesville. +

+ It’s important to differentiate this kind of political organizing from +influence campaigns; finding people who secretly agree with you isn’t the +same as convincing people to agree with you. The rise of phenomena like +nonbinary or otherwise nonconforming gender identities is often +characterized by reactionaries as the result of online brainwashing +campaigns that convince impressionable people that they have been secretly +queer all along. +

+ But the personal accounts of those who have come out tell a different story +where people who long harbored a secret about their gender were emboldened +by others coming forward and where people who knew that they were different +but lacked a vocabulary for discussing that difference learned the right +words from these low-cost means of finding people and learning about their +ideas. +

2. Deception

+ Lies and fraud are pernicious, and surveillance capitalism supercharges them +through targeting. If you want to sell a fraudulent payday loan or subprime +mortgage, surveillance capitalism can help you find people who are both +desperate and unsophisticated and thus receptive to your pitch. This +accounts for the rise of many phenomena, like multilevel marketing schemes, +in which deceptive claims about potential earnings and the efficacy of sales +techniques are targeted at desperate people by advertising against search +queries that indicate, for example, someone struggling with ill-advised +loans. +

+ Surveillance capitalism also abets fraud by making it easy to locate other +people who have been similarly deceived, forming a community of people who +reinforce one another’s false beliefs. Think of the +forums where people who are being victimized by multilevel marketing +frauds gather to trade tips on how to improve their luck in peddling the +product. +

+ Sometimes, online deception involves replacing someone’s correct beliefs +with incorrect ones, as it does in the anti-vaccination movement, whose +victims are often people who start out believing in vaccines but are +convinced by seemingly plausible evidence that leads them into the false +belief that vaccines are harmful. +

+ But it’s much more common for fraud to succeed when it doesn’t have to +displace a true belief. When my daughter contracted head lice at daycare, +one of the daycare workers told me I could get rid of them by treating her +hair and scalp with olive oil. I didn’t know anything about head lice, and I +assumed that the daycare worker did, so I tried it (it didn’t work, and it +doesn’t work). It’s easy to end up with false beliefs when you simply don’t +know any better and when those beliefs are conveyed by someone who seems to +know what they’re doing. +

+ This is pernicious and difficult — and it’s also the kind of thing the +internet can help guard against by making true information available, +especially in a form that exposes the underlying deliberations among parties +with sharply divergent views, such as Wikipedia. But it’s not brainwashing; +it’s fraud. In the majority of cases, +the victims of these fraud campaigns have an informational void filled in +the customary way, by consulting a seemingly reliable source. If I look up +the length of the Brooklyn Bridge and learn that it is 5,800 feet long, but +in reality, it is 5,989 feet long, the underlying deception is a problem, +but it’s a problem with a simple remedy. It’s a very different problem from +the anti-vax issue in which someone’s true belief is displaced by a false +one by means of sophisticated persuasion. +

3. Domination

+ Surveillance capitalism is the result of monopoly. Monopoly is the cause, +and surveillance capitalism and its negative outcomes are the effects of +monopoly. I’ll get into this in depth later, but for now, suffice it to say +that the tech industry has grown up with a radical theory of antitrust that +has allowed companies to grow by merging with their rivals, buying up their +nascent competitors, and expanding to control whole market verticals. +

+ One example of how monopolism aids in persuasion is through dominance: +Google makes editorial decisions about its algorithms that determine the +sort order of the responses to our queries. If a cabal of fraudsters have +set out to trick the world into thinking that the Brooklyn Bridge is 5,800 +feet long, and if Google gives a high search rank to this group in response +to queries like “How long is the Brooklyn Bridge?” then the +first eight or 10 screens’ worth of Google results could be wrong. And since +most people don’t go beyond the first couple of results — let alone the +first page of results — Google’s choice means that many +people will be deceived. +

+ Google’s dominance over search — more than 86% of web searches are performed +through Google — means that the way it orders its search results has an +outsized effect on public beliefs. Ironically, Google claims this is why it +can’t afford to have any transparency in its algorithm design: Google’s +search dominance makes the results of its sorting too important to risk +telling the world how it arrives at those results lest some bad actor +discover a flaw in the ranking system and exploit it to push its point of +view to the top of the search results. There’s an obvious remedy to a +company that is too big to audit: break it up into smaller pieces. +

+ Zuboff calls surveillance capitalism a “rogue capitalism” whose +data-hoarding and machine-learning techniques rob us of our free will. But +influence campaigns that seek to displace existing, correct beliefs with +false ones have an effect that is small and temporary while monopolistic +dominance over informational systems has massive, enduring +effects. Controlling the results to the world’s search queries means +controlling access both to arguments and their rebuttals and, thus, control +over much of the world’s beliefs. If our concern is how corporations are +foreclosing on our ability to make up our own minds and determine our own +futures, the impact of dominance far exceeds the impact of manipulation and +should be central to our analysis and any remedies we seek. +

4. Bypassing our rational faculties

+ This is the good stuff: using machine learning, +“dark patterns,” engagement hacking, and other techniques to +get us to do things that run counter to our better judgment. This is mind +control. +

+ Some of these techniques have proven devastatingly effective (if only in the +short term). The use of countdown timers on a purchase completion page can +create a sense of urgency that causes you to ignore the nagging internal +voice suggesting that you should shop around or sleep on your decision. The +use of people from your social graph in ads can provide “social +proof” that a purchase is worth making. Even the auction system +pioneered by eBay is calculated to play on our cognitive blind spots, +letting us feel like we “own” something because we bid on it, +thus encouraging us to bid again when we are outbid to ensure that +“our” things stay ours. +

+ Games are extraordinarily good at this. “Free to play” games +manipulate us through many techniques, such as presenting players with a +series of smoothly escalating challenges that create a sense of mastery and +accomplishment but which sharply transition into a set of challenges that +are impossible to overcome without paid upgrades. Add some social proof to +the mix — a stream of notifications about how well your friends are faring — +and before you know it, you’re buying virtual power-ups to get to the next +level. +

+ Companies have risen and fallen on these techniques, and the +“fallen” part is worth paying attention to. In general, living +things adapt to stimulus: Something that is very compelling or noteworthy +when you first encounter it fades with repetition until you stop noticing it +altogether. Consider the refrigerator hum that irritates you when it starts +up but disappears into the background so thoroughly that you only notice it +when it stops again. +

+ That’s why behavioral conditioning uses “intermittent reinforcement +schedules.” Instead of giving you a steady drip of encouragement or +setbacks, games and gamified services scatter rewards on a randomized +schedule — often enough to keep you interested and random enough that you +can never quite find the pattern that would make it boring. +

+ Intermittent reinforcement is a powerful behavioral tool, but it also +represents a collective action problem for surveillance capitalism. The +“engagement techniques” invented by the behaviorists of +surveillance capitalist companies are quickly copied across the whole sector +so that what starts as a mysteriously compelling fillip in the design of a +service—like “pull to refresh” or alerts when someone likes +your posts or side quests that your characters get invited to while in the +midst of main quests—quickly becomes dully ubiquitous. The +impossible-to-nail-down nonpattern of randomized drips from your phone +becomes a grey-noise wall of sound as every single app and site starts to +make use of whatever seems to be working at the time. +

+ From the surveillance capitalist’s point of view, our adaptive capacity is +like a harmful bacterium that deprives it of its food source — our attention +— and novel techniques for snagging that attention are like new antibiotics +that can be used to breach our defenses and destroy our +self-determination. And there are techniques like +that. Who can forget the Great Zynga Epidemic, when all of our friends were +caught in FarmVille’s endless, mindless dopamine loops? +But every new attention-commanding technique is jumped on by the whole +industry and used so indiscriminately that antibiotic resistance sets +in. Given enough repetition, almost all of us develop immunity to even the +most powerful techniques — by 2013, two years after Zynga’s peak, its user +base had halved. +

+ Not everyone, of course. Some people never adapt to stimulus, just as some +people never stop hearing the hum of the refrigerator. This is why most +people who are exposed to slot machines play them for a while and then move +on while a small and tragic minority liquidate their kids’ college funds, +buy adult diapers, and position themselves in front of a machine until they +collapse. +

+ But surveillance capitalism’s margins on behavioral modification +suck. Tripling the rate at which someone buys a widget sounds great unless +the base rate is way less than 1% with an improved rate of… still +less than 1%. Even penny slot machines pull down pennies for every spin +while surveillance capitalism rakes in infinitesimal penny fractions. +

+ Slot machines’ high returns mean that they can be profitable just by +draining the fortunes of the small rump of people who are pathologically +vulnerable to them and unable to adapt to their tricks. But surveillance +capitalism can’t survive on the fractional pennies it brings down from that +vulnerable sliver — that’s why, after the Great Zynga Epidemic had finally +burned itself out, the small number of still-addicted players left behind +couldn’t sustain it as a global phenomenon. And new powerful attention +weapons aren’t easy to find, as is evidenced by the long years since the +last time Zynga had a hit. Despite the hundreds of millions of dollars that +Zynga has to spend on developing new tools to blast through our adaptation, +it has never managed to repeat the lucky accident that let it snag so much +of our attention for a brief moment in 2009. Powerhouses like Supercell have +fared a little better, but they are rare and throw away many failures for +every success. +

+ The vulnerability of small segments of the population to dramatic, efficient +corporate manipulation is a real concern that’s worthy of our attention and +energy. But it’s not an existential threat to society. +

If data is the new oil, then surveillance capitalism’s engine has a leak

+ This adaptation problem offers an explanation for one of surveillance +capitalism’s most alarming traits: its relentless hunger for data and its +endless expansion of data-gathering capabilities through the spread of +sensors, online surveillance, and acquisition of data streams from third +parties. +

+ Zuboff observes this phenomenon and concludes that data must be very +valuable if surveillance capitalism is so hungry for it. (In her words: +“Just as industrial capitalism was driven to the continuous +intensification of the means of production, so surveillance capitalists and +their market players are now locked into the continuous intensification of +the means of behavioral modification and the gathering might of +instrumentarian power.”) But what if the voracious appetite is +because data has such a short half-life — because people become inured so +quickly to new, data-driven persuasion techniques — that the companies are +locked in an arms race with our limbic system? What if it’s all a Red +Queen’s race where they have to run ever faster — collect ever-more data — +just to stay in the same spot? +

+ Of course, all of Big Tech’s persuasion techniques work in concert with one +another, and collecting data is useful beyond mere behavioral trickery. +

+ If someone wants to recruit you to buy a refrigerator or join a pogrom, they +might use profiling and targeting to send messages to people they judge to +be good sales prospects. The messages themselves may be deceptive, making +claims about things you’re not very knowledgeable about (food safety and +energy efficiency or eugenics and historical claims about racial +superiority). They might use search engine optimization and/or armies of +fake reviewers and commenters and/or paid placement to dominate the +discourse so that any search for further information takes you back to their +messages. And finally, they may refine the different pitches using machine +learning and other techniques to figure out what kind of pitch works best on +someone like you. +

+ Each phase of this process benefits from surveillance: The more data they +have, the more precisely they can profile you and target you with specific +messages. Think of how you’d sell a fridge if you knew that the warranty on +your prospect’s fridge just expired and that they were expecting a tax +rebate in April. +

+ Also, the more data they have, the better they can craft deceptive messages +— if I know that you’re into genealogy, I might not try to feed you +pseudoscience about genetic differences between “races,” +sticking instead to conspiratorial secret histories of “demographic +replacement” and the like. +

+ Facebook also helps you locate people who have the same odious or antisocial +views as you. It makes it possible to find other people who want to carry +tiki torches through the streets of Charlottesville in Confederate +cosplay. It can help you find other people who want to join your militia and +go to the border to look for undocumented migrants to terrorize. It can help +you find people who share your belief that vaccines are poison and that the +Earth is flat. +

+ There is one way in which targeted advertising uniquely benefits those +advocating for socially unacceptable causes: It is invisible. Racism is +widely geographically dispersed, and there are few places where racists — +and only racists — gather. This is similar to the problem of selling +refrigerators in that potential refrigerator purchasers are geographically +dispersed and there are few places where you can buy an ad that will be +primarily seen by refrigerator customers. But buying a refrigerator is +socially acceptable while being a Nazi is not, so you can buy a billboard or +advertise in the newspaper sports section for your refrigerator business, +and the only potential downside is that your ad will be seen by a lot of +people who don’t want refrigerators, resulting in a lot of wasted expense. +

+ But even if you wanted to advertise your Nazi movement on a billboard or +prime-time TV or the sports section, you would struggle to find anyone +willing to sell you the space for your ad partly because they disagree with +your views and partly because they fear censure (boycott, reputational +damage, etc.) from other people who disagree with your views. +

+ Targeted ads solve this problem: On the internet, every ad unit can be +different for every person, meaning that you can buy ads that are only shown +to people who appear to be Nazis and not to people who hate Nazis. When +there’s spillover — when someone who hates racism is shown a racist +recruiting ad — there is some fallout; the platform or publication might get +an angry public or private denunciation. But the nature of the risk assumed +by an online ad buyer is different than the risks to a traditional publisher +or billboard owner who might want to run a Nazi ad. +

+ Online ads are placed by algorithms that broker between a diverse ecosystem +of self-serve ad platforms that anyone can buy an ad through, so the Nazi ad +that slips onto your favorite online publication isn’t seen as their moral +failing but rather as a failure in some distant, upstream ad supplier. When +a publication gets a complaint about an offensive ad that’s appearing in one +of its units, it can take some steps to block that ad, but the Nazi might +buy a slightly different ad from a different broker serving the same +unit. And in any event, internet users increasingly understand that when +they see an ad, it’s likely that the advertiser did not choose that +publication and that the publication has no idea who its advertisers are. +

+ These layers of indirection between advertisers and publishers serve as +moral buffers: Today’s moral consensus is largely that publishers shouldn’t +be held responsible for the ads that appear on their pages because they’re +not actively choosing to put those ads there. Because of this, Nazis are +able to overcome significant barriers to organizing their movement. +

+ Data has a complex relationship with domination. Being able to spy on your +customers can alert you to their preferences for your rivals and allow you +to head off your rivals at the pass. +

+ More importantly, if you can dominate the information space while also +gathering data, then you make other deceptive tactics stronger because it’s +harder to break out of the web of deceit you’re spinning. Domination — that +is, ultimately becoming a monopoly — and not the data itself is the +supercharger that makes every tactic worth pursuing because monopolistic +domination deprives your target of an escape route. +

+ If you’re a Nazi who wants to ensure that your prospects primarily see +deceptive, confirming information when they search for more, you can improve +your odds by seeding the search terms they use through your initial +communications. You don’t need to own the top 10 results for “voter +suppression” if you can convince your marks to confine their search +terms to “voter fraud,” which throws up a very different set of +search results. +

+ Surveillance capitalists are like stage mentalists who claim that their +extraordinary insights into human behavior let them guess the word that you +wrote down and folded up in your pocket but who really use shills, hidden +cameras, sleight of hand, and brute-force memorization to amaze you. +

+ Or perhaps they’re more like pick-up artists, the misogynistic cult that +promises to help awkward men have sex with women by teaching them +“neurolinguistic programming” phrases, body language +techniques, and psychological manipulation tactics like +“negging” — offering unsolicited negative feedback to women to +lower their self-esteem and prick their interest. +

+ Some pick-up artists eventually manage to convince women to go home with +them, but it’s not because these men have figured out how to bypass women’s +critical faculties. Rather, pick-up artists’ “success” stories +are a mix of women who were incapable of giving consent, women who were +coerced, women who were intoxicated, self-destructive women, and a few women +who were sober and in command of their faculties but who didn’t realize +straightaway that they were with terrible men but rectified the error as +soon as they could. +

+ Pick-up artists believe they have figured out a secret +back door that bypasses women’s critical faculties, but they haven’t. Many +of the tactics they deploy, like negging, became the butt of jokes (just +like people joke about bad ad targeting), and there’s a good chance that +anyone they try these tactics on will immediately recognize them and dismiss +the men who use them as irredeemable losers. +

+ Pick-up artists are proof that people can believe they have developed a +system of mind control even when it doesn’t +work. Pick-up artists simply exploit the fact that +one-in-a-million chances can come through for you if you make a million +attempts, and then they assume that the other 999,999 times, they simply +performed the technique incorrectly and commit themselves to doing better +next time. There’s only one group of people who find pick-up artist lore +reliably convincing: other would-be pick-up artists whose anxiety and +insecurity make them vulnerable to scammers and delusional men who convince +them that if they pay for tutelage and follow instructions, then they will +someday succeed. Pick-up artists assume they fail to entice women because +they are bad at being pick-up artists, not because pick-up artistry is +bullshit. Pick-up artists are bad at selling themselves to women, but +they’re much better at selling themselves to men who pay to learn the +secrets of pick-up artistry. +

+ Department store pioneer John Wanamaker is said to have lamented, +“Half the money I spend on advertising is wasted; the trouble is I +don’t know which half.” The fact that Wanamaker thought that only +half of his advertising spending was wasted is a tribute to the +persuasiveness of advertising executives, who are much +better at convincing potential clients to buy their services than they are +at convincing the general public to buy their clients’ wares. +

What is Facebook?

+ Facebook is heralded as the origin of all of our modern plagues, and it’s +not hard to see why. Some tech companies want to lock their users in but +make their money by monopolizing access to the market for apps for their +devices and gouging them on prices rather than by spying on them (like +Apple). Some companies don’t care about locking in users because they’ve +figured out how to spy on them no matter where they are and what they’re +doing and can turn that surveillance into money (Google). Facebook alone +among the Western tech giants has built a business based on locking in its +users and spying on them all the time. +

+ Facebook’s surveillance regime is really without parallel in the Western +world. Though Facebook tries to prevent itself from being visible on the +public web, hiding most of what goes on there from people unless they’re +logged into Facebook, the company has nevertheless booby-trapped the entire +web with surveillance tools in the form of Facebook “Like” +buttons that web publishers include on their sites to boost their Facebook +profiles. Facebook also makes various libraries and other useful code +snippets available to web publishers that act as surveillance tendrils on +the sites where they’re used, funneling information about visitors to the +site — newspapers, dating sites, message boards — to Facebook. +

+ Big Tech is able to practice surveillance not just because it is tech but +because it is big. +

+ Facebook offers similar tools to app developers, so the apps — games, fart +machines, business review services, apps for keeping abreast of your kid’s +schooling — you use will send information about your activities to Facebook +even if you don’t have a Facebook account and even if you don’t download or +use Facebook apps. On top of all that, Facebook buys data from third-party +brokers on shopping habits, physical location, use of “loyalty” +programs, financial transactions, etc., and cross-references that with the +dossiers it develops on activity on Facebook and with apps and the public +web. +

+ Though it’s easy to integrate the web with Facebook — linking to news +stories and such — Facebook products are generally not available to be +integrated back into the web itself. You can embed a tweet in a Facebook +post, but if you embed a Facebook post in a tweet, you just get a link back +to Facebook and must log in before you can see it. Facebook has used extreme +technological and legal countermeasures to prevent rivals from allowing +their users to embed Facebook snippets in competing services or to create +alternative interfaces to Facebook that merge your Facebook inbox with those +of other services that you use. +

+ And Facebook is incredibly popular, with 2.3 billion claimed users (though +many believe this figure to be inflated). Facebook has been used to organize +genocidal pogroms, racist riots, anti-vaccination movements, flat Earth +cults, and the political lives of some of the world’s ugliest, most brutal +autocrats. There are some really alarming things going on in the world, and +Facebook is implicated in many of them, so it’s easy to conclude that these +bad things are the result of Facebook’s mind-control system, which it rents +out to anyone with a few bucks to spend. +

+ To understand what role Facebook plays in the formulation and mobilization +of antisocial movements, we need to understand the dual nature of Facebook. +

+ Because it has a lot of users and a lot of data about those users, Facebook +is a very efficient tool for locating people with hard-to-find traits, the +kinds of traits that are widely diffused in the population such that +advertisers have historically struggled to find a cost-effective way to +reach them. Think back to refrigerators: Most of us only replace our major +appliances a few times in our entire lives. If you’re a refrigerator +manufacturer or retailer, you have these brief windows in the life of a +consumer during which they are pondering a purchase, and you have to somehow +reach them. Anyone who’s ever registered a title change after buying a house +can attest that appliance manufacturers are incredibly desperate to reach +anyone who has even the slenderest chance of being in the market for a new +fridge. +

+ Facebook makes finding people shopping for refrigerators a +lot easier. It can target ads to people who’ve +registered a new home purchase, to people who’ve searched for refrigerator +buying advice, to people who have complained about their fridge dying, or +any combination thereof. It can even target people who’ve recently bought +other kitchen appliances on the theory that someone +who’s just replaced their stove and dishwasher might be in a fridge-buying +kind of mood. The vast majority of people who are reached by these ads will +not be in the market for a new fridge, but — crucially — the percentage of +people who are looking for fridges that these ads reach +is much larger than it is than for any group that might +be subjected to traditional, offline targeted refrigerator marketing. +

+ Facebook also makes it a lot easier to find people who have the same rare +disease as you, which might have been impossible in earlier eras — the +closest fellow sufferer might otherwise be hundreds of miles away. It makes +it easier to find people who went to the same high school as you even though +decades have passed and your former classmates have all been scattered to +the four corners of the Earth. +

+ Facebook also makes it much easier to find people who hold the same rare +political beliefs as you. If you’ve always harbored a secret affinity for +socialism but never dared utter this aloud lest you be demonized by your +neighbors, Facebook can help you discover other people who feel the same way +(and it might just demonstrate to you that your affinity is more widespread +than you ever suspected). It can make it easier to find people who share +your sexual identity. And again, it can help you to understand that what +you thought was a shameful secret that affected only you was really a widely +shared trait, giving you both comfort and the courage to come out to the +people in your life. +

+ All of this presents a dilemma for Facebook: Targeting makes the company’s +ads more effective than traditional ads, but it also lets advertisers see +just how effective their ads are. While advertisers are pleased to learn +that Facebook ads are more effective than ads on systems with less +sophisticated targeting, advertisers can also see that in nearly every case, +the people who see their ads ignore them. Or, at best, the ads work on a +subconscious level, creating nebulous unmeasurables like “brand +recognition.” This means that the price per ad is very low in nearly +every case. +

+ To make things worse, many Facebook groups spark precious little +discussion. Your little-league soccer team, the people with the same rare +disease as you, and the people you share a political affinity with may +exchange the odd flurry of messages at critical junctures, but on a daily +basis, there’s not much to say to your old high school chums or other +hockey-card collectors. +

+ With nothing but “organic” discussion, Facebook would not +generate enough traffic to sell enough ads to make the money it needs to +continually expand by buying up its competitors while returning handsome +sums to its investors. +

+ So Facebook has to gin up traffic by sidetracking its own forums: Every time +Facebook’s algorithm injects controversial materials — inflammatory +political articles, conspiracy theories, outrage stories — into a group, it +can hijack that group’s nominal purpose with its desultory discussions and +supercharge those discussions by turning them into bitter, unproductive +arguments that drag on and on. Facebook is optimized for engagement, not +happiness, and it turns out that automated systems are pretty good at +figuring out things that people will get angry about. +

+ Facebook can modify our behavior but only in a couple +of trivial ways. First, it can lock in all your friends and family members +so that you check and check and check with Facebook to find out what they +are up to; and second, it can make you angry and anxious. It can force you +to choose between being interrupted constantly by updates — a process that +breaks your concentration and makes it hard to be introspective — and +staying in touch with your friends. This is a very limited form of mind +control, and it can only really make us miserable, angry, and anxious. +

+ This is why Facebook’s targeting systems — both the ones it shows to +advertisers and the ones that let users find people who share their +interests — are so next-gen and smooth and easy to use as well as why its +message boards have a toolset that seems like it hasn’t changed since the +mid-2000s. If Facebook delivered an equally flexible, sophisticated +message-reading system to its users, those users could defend themselves +against being nonconsensually eyeball-fucked with Donald Trump headlines. +

+ The more time you spend on Facebook, the more ads it gets to show you. The +solution to Facebook’s ads only working one in a thousand times is for the +company to try to increase how much time you spend on Facebook by a factor +of a thousand. Rather than thinking of Facebook as a company that has +figured out how to show you exactly the right ad in exactly the right way to +get you to do what its advertisers want, think of it as a company that has +figured out how to make you slog through an endless torrent of arguments +even though they make you miserable, spending so much time on the site that +it eventually shows you at least one ad that you respond to. +

Monopoly and the right to the future tense

+ Zuboff and her cohort are particularly alarmed at the extent to which +surveillance allows corporations to influence our decisions, taking away +something she poetically calls “the right to the future tense” +— that is, the right to decide for yourself what you will do in the future. +

+ It’s true that advertising can tip the scales one way or another: When +you’re thinking of buying a fridge, a timely fridge ad might end the search +on the spot. But Zuboff puts enormous and undue weight on the persuasive +power of surveillance-based influence techniques. Most of these don’t work +very well, and the ones that do won’t work for very long. The makers of +these influence tools are confident they will someday refine them into +systems of total control, but they are hardly unbiased observers, and the +risks from their dreams coming true are very speculative. +

+ By contrast, Zuboff is rather sanguine about 40 years of lax antitrust +practice that has allowed a handful of companies to dominate the internet, +ushering in an information age with, as one person +on Twitter noted, five giant websites each filled with screenshots +of the other four. +

+ However, if we are to be alarmed that we might lose the right to choose for +ourselves what our future will hold, then monopoly’s nonspeculative, +concrete, here-and-now harms should be front and center in our debate over +tech policy. +

+ Start with “digital rights management.” In 1998, Bill Clinton +signed the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) into law. It’s a complex +piece of legislation with many controversial clauses but none more so than +Section 1201, the “anti-circumvention” rule. +

+ This is a blanket ban on tampering with systems that restrict access to +copyrighted works. The ban is so thoroughgoing that it prohibits removing a +copyright lock even when no copyright infringement takes place. This is by +design: The activities that the DMCA’s Section 1201 sets out to ban are not +copyright infringements; rather, they are legal activities that frustrate +manufacturers’ commercial plans. +

+ For example, Section 1201’s first major application was on DVD players as a +means of enforcing the region coding built into those devices. DVD-CCA, the +body that standardized DVDs and DVD players, divided the world into six +regions and specified that DVD players must check each disc to determine +which regions it was authorized to be played in. DVD players would have +their own corresponding region (a DVD player bought in the U.S. would be +region 1 while one bought in India would be region 5). If the player and the +disc’s region matched, the player would play the disc; otherwise, it would +reject it. +

+ However, watching a lawfully produced disc in a country other than the one +where you purchased it is not copyright infringement — it’s the +opposite. Copyright law imposes this duty on customers for a movie: You must +go into a store, find a licensed disc, and pay the asking price. Do that — +and nothing else — and you and copyright are square +with one another. +

+ The fact that a movie studio wants to charge Indians less than Americans or +release in Australia later than it releases in the U.K. has no bearing on +copyright law. Once you lawfully acquire a DVD, it is no copyright +infringement to watch it no matter where you happen to be. +

+ So DVD and DVD player manufacturers would not be able to use accusations of +abetting copyright infringement to punish manufacturers who made +noncompliant players that would play discs from any region or repair shops +that modified players to let you watch out-of-region discs or software +programmers who created programs to let you do this. +

+ That’s where Section 1201 of the DMCA comes in: By banning tampering with an +“access control,” the rule gave manufacturers and rights +holders standing to sue competitors who released superior products with +lawful features that the market demanded (in this case, region-free +players). +

+ This is an odious scam against consumers, but as time went by, Section 1201 +grew to encompass a rapidly expanding constellation of devices and services +as canny manufacturers have realized certain things: +

  • + Any device with software in it contains a “copyrighted work” — +i.e., the software. +

  • + A device can be designed so that reconfiguring the software requires +bypassing an “access control for copyrighted works,” which is a +potential felony under Section 1201. +

  • + Thus, companies can control their customers’ behavior after they take home +their purchases by designing products so that all unpermitted uses require +modifications that fall afoul of Section 1201. +

+ Section 1201 then becomes a means for manufacturers of all descriptions to +force their customers to arrange their affairs to benefit the manufacturers’ +shareholders instead of themselves. +

+ This manifests in many ways: from a new generation of inkjet printers that +use countermeasures to prevent third-party ink that cannot be bypassed +without legal risks to similar systems in tractors that prevent third-party +technicians from swapping in the manufacturer’s own parts that are not +recognized by the tractor’s control system until it is supplied with a +manufacturer’s unlock code. +

+ Closer to home, Apple’s iPhones use these measures to prevent both +third-party service and third-party software installation. This allows Apple +to decide when an iPhone is beyond repair and must be shredded and +landfilled as opposed to the iPhone’s purchaser. (Apple is notorious for its +environmentally catastrophic policy of destroying old electronics rather +than permitting them to be cannibalized for parts.) This is a very useful +power to wield, especially in light of CEO Tim Cook’s January 2019 warning +to investors that the company’s profits are endangered by customers choosing +to hold onto their phones for longer rather than replacing them. +

+ Apple’s use of copyright locks also allows it to establish a monopoly over +how its customers acquire software for their mobile devices. The App Store’s +commercial terms guarantee Apple a share of all revenues generated by the +apps sold there, meaning that Apple gets paid when you buy an app from its +store and then continues to get paid every time you buy something using that +app. This comes out of the bottom line of software developers, who must +either charge more or accept lower profits for their products. +

+ Crucially, Apple’s use of copyright locks gives it the power to make +editorial decisions about which apps you may and may not install on your own +device. Apple has used this power to reject +dictionaries for containing obscene words; to limit +political speech, especially from apps that make sensitive political +commentary such as an app that notifies you every time a U.S. drone kills +someone somewhere in the world; and to object +to a game that commented on the Israel-Palestine conflict. +

+ Apple often justifies monopoly power over software installation in the name +of security, arguing that its vetting of apps for its store means that it +can guard its users against apps that contain surveillance code. But this +cuts both ways. In China, the government ordered +Apple to prohibit the sale of privacy tools like VPNs with the +exception of VPNs that had deliberately introduced flaws designed to let the +Chinese state eavesdrop on users. Because Apple uses technological +countermeasures — with legal backstops — to block customers from installing +unauthorized apps, Chinese iPhone owners cannot readily (or legally) acquire +VPNs that would protect them from Chinese state snooping. +

+ Zuboff calls surveillance capitalism a “rogue capitalism.” +Theoreticians of capitalism claim that its virtue is that it aggregates information in +the form of consumers’ decisions, producing efficient +markets. Surveillance capitalism’s supposed power to rob its victims of +their free will through computationally supercharged influence campaigns +means that our markets no longer aggregate customers’ decisions because we +customers no longer decide — we are given orders by surveillance +capitalism’s mind-control rays. +

+ If our concern is that markets cease to function when consumers can no +longer make choices, then copyright locks should concern us at +least as much as influence campaigns. An influence +campaign might nudge you to buy a certain brand of phone; but the copyright +locks on that phone absolutely determine where you get it serviced, which +apps can run on it, and when you have to throw it away rather than fixing +it. +

Search order and the right to the future tense

+ Markets are posed as a kind of magic: By discovering otherwise hidden +information conveyed by the free choices of consumers, those consumers’ +local knowledge is integrated into a self-correcting system that makes +efficient allocations—more efficient than any computer could calculate. But +monopolies are incompatible with that notion. When you only have one app +store, the owner of the store — not the consumer — decides on the range of +choices. As Boss Tweed once said, “I don’t care who does the electing, +so long as I get to do the nominating.” A monopolized market is an +election whose candidates are chosen by the monopolist. +

+ This ballot rigging is made more pernicious by the existence of monopolies +over search order. Google’s search market share is about 90%. When Google’s +ranking algorithm puts a result for a popular search term in its top 10, +that helps determine the behavior of millions of people. If Google’s answer +to “Are vaccines dangerous?” is a page that rebuts anti-vax +conspiracy theories, then a sizable portion of the public will learn that +vaccines are safe. If, on the other hand, Google sends those people to a +site affirming the anti-vax conspiracies, a sizable portion of those +millions will come away convinced that vaccines are dangerous. +

+ Google’s algorithm is often tricked into serving disinformation as a +prominent search result. But in these cases, Google isn’t persuading people +to change their minds; it’s just presenting something untrue as fact when +the user has no cause to doubt it. +

+ This is true whether the search is for “Are vaccines +dangerous?” or “best restaurants near me.” Most users +will never look past the first page of search results, and when the +overwhelming majority of people all use the same search engine, the ranking +algorithm deployed by that search engine will determine myriad outcomes +(whether to adopt a child, whether to have cancer surgery, where to eat +dinner, where to move, where to apply for a job) to a degree that vastly +outstrips any behavioral outcomes dictated by algorithmic persuasion +techniques. +

+ Many of the questions we ask search engines have no empirically correct +answers: “Where should I eat dinner?” is not an objective +question. Even questions that do have correct answers (“Are vaccines +dangerous?”) don’t have one empirically superior source for that +answer. Many pages affirm the safety of vaccines, so which one goes first? +Under conditions of competition, consumers can choose from many search +engines and stick with the one whose algorithmic judgment suits them best, +but under conditions of monopoly, we all get our answers from the same +place. +

+ Google’s search dominance isn’t a matter of pure merit: The company has +leveraged many tactics that would have been prohibited under classical, +pre-Ronald-Reagan antitrust enforcement standards to attain its +dominance. After all, this is a company that has developed two major +products: a really good search engine and a pretty good Hotmail clone. Every +other major success it’s had — Android, YouTube, Google Maps, etc. — has +come through an acquisition of a nascent competitor. Many of the company’s +key divisions, such as the advertising technology of DoubleClick, violate +the historical antitrust principle of structural separation, which forbade +firms from owning subsidiaries that competed with their +customers. Railroads, for example, were barred from owning freight companies +that competed with the shippers whose freight they carried. +

+ If we’re worried about giant companies subverting markets by stripping +consumers of their ability to make free choices, then vigorous antitrust +enforcement seems like an excellent remedy. If we’d denied Google the right +to effect its many mergers, we would also have probably denied it its total +search dominance. Without that dominance, the pet theories, biases, errors +(and good judgment, too) of Google search engineers and product managers +would not have such an outsized effect on consumer choice. +

+ This goes for many other companies. Amazon, a classic surveillance +capitalist, is obviously the dominant tool for searching Amazon — though +many people find their way to Amazon through Google searches and Facebook +posts — and obviously, Amazon controls Amazon search. That means that +Amazon’s own self-serving editorial choices—like promoting its own house +brands over rival goods from its sellers as well as its own pet theories, +biases, and errors— determine much of what we buy on Amazon. And since +Amazon is the dominant e-commerce retailer outside of China and since it +attained that dominance by buying up both large rivals and nascent +competitors in defiance of historical antitrust rules, we can blame the +monopoly for stripping consumers of their right to the future tense and the +ability to shape markets by making informed choices. +

+ Not every monopolist is a surveillance capitalist, but that doesn’t mean +they’re not able to shape consumer choices in wide-ranging ways. Zuboff +lauds Apple for its App Store and iTunes Store, insisting that adding price +tags to the features on its platforms has been the secret to resisting +surveillance and thus creating markets. But Apple is the only retailer +allowed to sell on its platforms, and it’s the second-largest mobile device +vendor in the world. The independent software vendors that sell through +Apple’s marketplace accuse the company of the same surveillance sins as +Amazon and other big retailers: spying on its customers to find lucrative +new products to launch, effectively using independent software vendors as +free-market researchers, then forcing them out of any markets they discover. +

+ Because of its use of copyright locks, Apple’s mobile customers are not +legally allowed to switch to a rival retailer for its apps if they want to +do so on an iPhone. Apple, obviously, is the only entity that gets to decide +how it ranks the results of search queries in its stores. These decisions +ensure that some apps are often installed (because they appear on page one) +and others are never installed (because they appear on page one +million). Apple’s search-ranking design decisions have a vastly more +significant effect on consumer behaviors than influence campaigns delivered +by surveillance capitalism’s ad-serving bots. +

Monopolists can afford sleeping pills for watchdogs

+ Only the most extreme market ideologues think that markets can self-regulate +without state oversight. Markets need watchdogs — regulators, lawmakers, and +other elements of democratic control — to keep them honest. When these +watchdogs sleep on the job, then markets cease to aggregate consumer choices +because those choices are constrained by illegitimate and deceptive +activities that companies are able to get away with because no one is +holding them to account. +

+ But this kind of regulatory capture doesn’t come cheap. In competitive +sectors, where rivals are constantly eroding one another’s margins, +individual firms lack the surplus capital to effectively lobby for laws and +regulations that serve their ends. +

+ Many of the harms of surveillance capitalism are the result of weak or +nonexistent regulation. Those regulatory vacuums spring from the power of +monopolists to resist stronger regulation and to tailor what regulation +exists to permit their existing businesses. +

+ Here’s an example: When firms over-collect and over-retain our data, they +are at increased risk of suffering a breach — you can’t leak data you never +collected, and once you delete all copies of that data, you can no longer +leak it. For more than a decade, we’ve lived through an endless parade of +ever-worsening data breaches, each one uniquely horrible in the scale of +data breached and the sensitivity of that data. +

+ But still, firms continue to over-collect and over-retain our data for three +reasons: +

+ 1. They are locked in the aforementioned limbic arms +race with our capacity to shore up our attentional defense systems to resist +their new persuasion techniques. They’re also locked in an arms +race with their competitors to find new ways to target people for sales +pitches. As soon as they discover a soft spot in our attentional defenses (a +counterintuitive, unobvious way to target potential refrigerator buyers), +the public begins to wise up to the tactic, and their competitors leap on +it, hastening the day in which all potential refrigerator buyers have been +inured to the pitch. +

+ 2. They believe the surveillance capitalism +story. Data is cheap to aggregate and store, and both proponents +and opponents of surveillance capitalism have assured managers and product +designers that if you collect enough data, you will be able to perform +sorcerous acts of mind control, thus supercharging your sales. Even if you +never figure out how to profit from the data, someone else will eventually +offer to buy it from you to give it a try. This is the hallmark of all +economic bubbles: acquiring an asset on the assumption that someone else +will buy it from you for more than you paid for it, often to sell to someone +else at an even greater price. +

+ 3. The penalties for leaking data are +negligible. Most countries limit these penalties to actual +damages, meaning that consumers who’ve had their data breached have to show +actual monetary harms to get a reward. In 2014, Home Depot disclosed that it +had lost credit-card data for 53 million of its customers, but it settled +the matter by paying those customers about $0.34 each — and a third of that +$0.34 wasn’t even paid in cash. It took the form of a credit to procure a +largely ineffectual credit-monitoring service. +

+ But the harms from breaches are much more extensive than these +actual-damages rules capture. Identity thieves and fraudsters are wily and +endlessly inventive. All the vast breaches of our century are being +continuously recombined, the data sets merged and mined for new ways to +victimize the people whose data was present in them. Any reasonable, +evidence-based theory of deterrence and compensation for breaches would not +confine damages to actual damages but rather would allow users to claim +these future harms. +

+ However, even the most ambitious privacy rules, such as the EU General Data +Protection Regulation, fall far short of capturing the negative +externalities of the platforms’ negligent over-collection and +over-retention, and what penalties they do provide are not aggressively +pursued by regulators. +

+ This tolerance of — or indifference to — data over-collection and +over-retention can be ascribed in part to the sheer lobbying muscle of the +platforms. They are so profitable that they can handily afford to divert +gigantic sums to fight any real change — that is, change that would force +them to internalize the costs of their surveillance activities. +

+ And then there’s state surveillance, which the surveillance capitalism story +dismisses as a relic of another era when the big worry was being jailed for +your dissident speech, not having your free will stripped away with machine +learning. +

+ But state surveillance and private surveillance are intimately related. As +we saw when Apple was conscripted by the Chinese government as a vital +collaborator in state surveillance, the only really affordable and tractable +way to conduct mass surveillance on the scale practiced by modern states — +both “free” and autocratic states — is to suborn commercial +services. +

+ Whether it’s Google being used as a location tracking tool by local law +enforcement across the U.S. or the use of social media tracking by the +Department of Homeland Security to build dossiers on participants in +protests against Immigration and Customs Enforcement’s family separation +practices, any hard limits on surveillance capitalism would hamstring the +state’s own surveillance capability. Without Palantir, Amazon, Google, and +other major tech contractors, U.S. cops would not be able to spy on Black +people, ICE would not be able to manage the caging of children at the U.S. +border, and state welfare systems would not be able to purge their rolls by +dressing up cruelty as empiricism and claiming that poor and vulnerable +people are ineligible for assistance. At least some of the states’ +unwillingness to take meaningful action to curb surveillance should be +attributed to this symbiotic relationship. There is no mass state +surveillance without mass commercial surveillance. +

+ Monopolism is key to the project of mass state surveillance. It’s true that +smaller tech firms are apt to be less well-defended than Big Tech, whose +security experts are drawn from the tops of their field and who are given +enormous resources to secure and monitor their systems against +intruders. But smaller firms also have less to protect: fewer users whose +data is more fragmented across more systems and have to be suborned one at a +time by state actors. +

+ A concentrated tech sector that works with authorities is a much more +powerful ally in the project of mass state surveillance than a fragmented +one composed of smaller actors. The U.S. tech sector is small enough that +all of its top executives fit around a single boardroom table in Trump Tower +in 2017, shortly after Trump’s inauguration. Most of its biggest players bid +to win JEDI, the Pentagon’s $10 billion Joint Enterprise Defense +Infrastructure cloud contract. Like other highly concentrated industries, +Big Tech rotates its key employees in and out of government service, sending +them to serve in the Department of Defense and the White House, then hiring +ex-Pentagon and ex-DOD top staffers and officers to work in their own +government relations departments. +

+ They can even make a good case for doing this: After all, when there are +only four or five big companies in an industry, everyone qualified to +regulate those companies has served as an executive in at least a couple of +them — because, likewise, when there are only five companies in an industry, +everyone qualified for a senior role at any of them is by definition working +at one of the other ones. +

+ While surveillance doesn’t cause monopolies, monopolies certainly abet +surveillance. +

+ Industries that are competitive are fragmented — composed of companies that +are at each other’s throats all the time and eroding one another’s margins +in bids to steal their best customers. This leaves them with much more +limited capital to use to lobby for favorable rules and a much harder job of +getting everyone to agree to pool their resources to benefit the industry as +a whole. +

+ Surveillance combined with machine learning is supposed to be an existential +crisis, a species-defining moment at which our free will is just a few more +advances in the field from being stripped away. I am skeptical of this +claim, but I do think that tech poses an existential +threat to our society and possibly our species. +

+ But that threat grows out of monopoly. +

+ One of the consequences of tech’s regulatory capture is that it can shift +liability for poor security decisions onto its customers and the wider +society. It is absolutely normal in tech for companies to obfuscate the +workings of their products, to make them deliberately hard to understand, +and to threaten security researchers who seek to independently audit those +products. +

+ IT is the only field in which this is practiced: No one builds a bridge or a +hospital and keeps the composition of the steel or the equations used to +calculate load stresses a secret. It is a frankly bizarre practice that +leads, time and again, to grotesque security defects on farcical scales, +with whole classes of devices being revealed as vulnerable long after they +are deployed in the field and put into sensitive places. +

+ The monopoly power that keeps any meaningful consequences for breaches at +bay means that tech companies continue to build terrible products that are +insecure by design and that end up integrated into our lives, in possession +of our data, and connected to our physical world. For years, Boeing has +struggled with the aftermath of a series of bad technology decisions that +made its 737 fleet a global pariah, a rare instance in which bad tech +decisions have been seriously punished in the market. +

+ These bad security decisions are compounded yet again by the use of +copyright locks to enforce business-model decisions against +consumers. Recall that these locks have become the go-to means for shaping +consumer behavior, making it technically impossible to use third-party ink, +insulin, apps, or service depots in connection with your lawfully acquired +property. +

+ Recall also that these copyright locks are backstopped by legislation (such +as Section 1201 of the DMCA or Article 6 of the 2001 EU Copyright Directive) +that ban tampering with (“circumventing”) them, and these +statutes have been used to threaten security researchers who make +disclosures about vulnerabilities without permission from manufacturers. +

+ This amounts to a manufacturer’s veto over safety warnings and +criticism. While this is far from the legislative intent of the DMCA and its +sister statutes around the world, Congress has not intervened to clarify the +statute nor will it because to do so would run counter to the interests of +powerful, large firms whose lobbying muscle is unstoppable. +

+ Copyright locks are a double whammy: They create bad security decisions that +can’t be freely investigated or discussed. If markets are supposed to be +machines for aggregating information (and if surveillance capitalism’s +notional mind-control rays are what make it a “rogue +capitalism” because it denies consumers the power to make decisions), +then a program of legally enforced ignorance of the risks of products makes +monopolism even more of a “rogue capitalism” than surveillance +capitalism’s influence campaigns. +

+ And unlike mind-control rays, enforced silence over security is an +immediate, documented problem, and it does constitute +an existential threat to our civilization and possibly our species. The +proliferation of insecure devices — especially devices that spy on us and +especially when those devices also can manipulate the physical world by, +say, steering your car or flipping a breaker at a power station — is a kind +of technology debt. +

+ In software design, “technology debt” refers to old, baked-in +decisions that turn out to be bad ones in hindsight. Perhaps a long-ago +developer decided to incorporate a networking protocol made by a vendor that +has since stopped supporting it. But everything in the product still relies +on that superannuated protocol, and so, with each revision, the product team +has to work around this obsolete core, adding compatibility layers, +surrounding it with security checks that try to shore up its defenses, and +so on. These Band-Aid measures compound the debt because every subsequent +revision has to make allowances for them, too, like +interest mounting on a predatory subprime loan. And like a subprime loan, +the interest mounts faster than you can hope to pay it off: The product team +has to put so much energy into maintaining this complex, brittle system that +they don’t have any time left over to refactor the product from the ground +up and “pay off the debt” once and for all. +

+ Typically, technology debt results in a technological bankruptcy: The +product gets so brittle and unsustainable that it fails +catastrophically. Think of the antiquated COBOL-based banking and accounting +systems that fell over at the start of the pandemic emergency when +confronted with surges of unemployment claims. Sometimes that ends the +product; sometimes it takes the company down with it. Being caught in the +default of a technology debt is scary and traumatic, just like losing your +house due to bankruptcy is scary and traumatic. +

+ But the technology debt created by copyright locks isn’t individual debt; +it’s systemic. Everyone in the world is exposed to this over-leverage, as +was the case with the 2008 financial crisis. When that debt comes due — when +we face a cascade of security breaches that threaten global shipping and +logistics, the food supply, pharmaceutical production pipelines, emergency +communications, and other critical systems that are accumulating technology +debt in part due to the presence of deliberately insecure and deliberately +unauditable copyright locks — it will indeed pose an existential risk. +

Privacy and monopoly

+ Many tech companies are gripped by an orthodoxy that holds that if they just +gather enough data on enough of our activities, everything else is possible +— the mind control and endless profits. This is an unfalsifiable hypothesis: +If data gives a tech company even a tiny improvement in behavior prediction +and modification, the company declares that it has taken the first step +toward global domination with no end in sight. If a company +fails to attain any improvements from gathering and +analyzing data, it declares success to be just around the corner, attainable +once more data is in hand. +

+ Surveillance tech is far from the first industry to embrace a nonsensical, +self-serving belief that harms the rest of the world, and it is not the +first industry to profit handsomely from such a delusion. Long before +hedge-fund managers were claiming (falsely) that they could beat the +S&P 500, there were plenty of other “respectable” +industries that have been revealed as quacks in hindsight. From the makers +of radium suppositories (a real thing!) to the cruel sociopaths who claimed +they could “cure” gay people, history is littered with the +formerly respectable titans of discredited industries. +

+ This is not to say that there’s nothing wrong with Big Tech and its +ideological addiction to data. While surveillance’s benefits are mostly +overstated, its harms are, if anything, understated. +

+ There’s real irony here. The belief in surveillance capitalism as a +“rogue capitalism” is driven by the belief that markets +wouldn’t tolerate firms that are gripped by false beliefs. An oil company +that has false beliefs about where the oil is will eventually go broke +digging dry wells after all. +

+ But monopolists get to do terrible things for a long time before they pay +the price. Think of how concentration in the finance sector allowed the +subprime crisis to fester as bond-rating agencies, regulators, investors, +and critics all fell under the sway of a false belief that complex +mathematics could construct “fully hedged” debt instruments +that could not possibly default. A small bank that engaged in this kind of +malfeasance would simply go broke rather than outrunning the inevitable +crisis, perhaps growing so big that it averted it altogether. But large +banks were able to continue to attract investors, and when they finally +did come a-cropper, the world’s governments bailed them +out. The worst offenders of the subprime crisis are bigger than they were in +2008, bringing home more profits and paying their execs even larger sums. +

+ Big Tech is able to practice surveillance not just because it is tech but +because it is big. The reason every web publisher +embeds a Facebook “Like” button is that Facebook dominates the +internet’s social media referrals — and every one of those +“Like” buttons spies on everyone who lands on a page that +contains them (see also: Google Analytics embeds, Twitter buttons, etc.). +

+ The reason the world’s governments have been slow to create meaningful +penalties for privacy breaches is that Big Tech’s concentration produces +huge profits that can be used to lobby against those penalties — and Big +Tech’s concentration means that the companies involved are able to arrive at +a unified negotiating position that supercharges the lobbying. +

+ The reason that the smartest engineers in the world want to work for Big +Tech is that Big Tech commands the lion’s share of tech industry jobs. +

+ The reason people who are aghast at Facebook’s and Google’s and Amazon’s +data-handling practices continue to use these services is that all their +friends are on Facebook; Google dominates search; and Amazon has put all the +local merchants out of business. +

+ Competitive markets would weaken the companies’ lobbying muscle by reducing +their profits and pitting them against each other in regulatory forums. It +would give customers other places to go to get their online services. It +would make the companies small enough to regulate and pave the way to +meaningful penalties for breaches. It would let engineers with ideas that +challenged the surveillance orthodoxy raise capital to compete with the +incumbents. It would give web publishers multiple ways to reach audiences +and make the case against Facebook and Google and Twitter embeds. +

+ In other words, while surveillance doesn’t cause monopolies, monopolies +certainly abet surveillance. +

Ronald Reagan, pioneer of tech monopolism

+ Technology exceptionalism is a sin, whether it’s practiced by technology’s +blind proponents or by its critics. Both of these camps are prone to +explaining away monopolistic concentration by citing some special +characteristic of the tech industry, like network effects or first-mover +advantage. The only real difference between these two groups is that the +tech apologists say monopoly is inevitable so we should just let tech get +away with its abuses while competition regulators in the U.S. and the EU say +monopoly is inevitable so we should punish tech for its abuses but not try +to break up the monopolies. +

+ To understand how tech became so monopolistic, it’s useful to look at the +dawn of the consumer tech industry: 1979, the year the Apple II Plus +launched and became the first successful home computer. That also happens to +be the year that Ronald Reagan hit the campaign trail for the 1980 +presidential race — a race he won, leading to a radical shift in the way +that antitrust concerns are handled in America. Reagan’s cohort of +politicians — including Margaret Thatcher in the U.K., Brian Mulroney in +Canada, Helmut Kohl in Germany, and Augusto Pinochet in Chile — went on to +enact similar reforms that eventually spread around the world. +

+ Antitrust’s story began nearly a century before all that with laws like the +Sherman Act, which took aim at monopolists on the grounds that monopolies +were bad in and of themselves — squeezing out competitors, creating +“diseconomies of scale” (when a company is so big that its +constituent parts go awry and it is seemingly helpless to address the +problems), and capturing their regulators to such a degree that they can get +away with a host of evils. +

+ Then came a fabulist named Robert Bork, a former solicitor general who +Reagan appointed to the powerful U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit +and who had created an alternate legislative history of the Sherman Act and +its successors out of whole cloth. Bork insisted that these statutes were +never targeted at monopolies (despite a wealth of evidence to the contrary, +including the transcribed speeches of the acts’ authors) but, rather, that +they were intended to prevent “consumer harm” — in the form of +higher prices. +

+ Bork was a crank, but he was a crank with a theory that rich people really +liked. Monopolies are a great way to make rich people richer by allowing +them to receive “monopoly rents” (that is, bigger profits) and +capture regulators, leading to a weaker, more favorable regulatory +environment with fewer protections for customers, suppliers, the +environment, and workers. +

+ Bork’s theories were especially palatable to the same power brokers who +backed Reagan, and Reagan’s Department of Justice and other agencies began +to incorporate Bork’s antitrust doctrine into their enforcement decisions +(Reagan even put Bork up for a Supreme Court seat, but Bork flunked the +Senate confirmation hearing so badly that, 40 years later, D.C. insiders use +the term “borked” to refer to any catastrophically bad +political performance). +

+ Little by little, Bork’s theories entered the mainstream, and their backers +began to infiltrate the legal education field, even putting on junkets where +members of the judiciary were treated to lavish meals, fun outdoor +activities, and seminars where they were indoctrinated into the consumer +harm theory of antitrust. The more Bork’s theories took hold, the more money +the monopolists were making — and the more surplus capital they had at their +disposal to lobby for even more Borkian antitrust influence campaigns. +

+ The history of Bork’s antitrust theories is a really good example of the +kind of covertly engineered shifts in public opinion that Zuboff warns us +against, where fringe ideas become mainstream orthodoxy. But Bork didn’t +change the world overnight. He played a very long game, for over a +generation, and he had a tailwind because the same forces that backed +oligarchic antitrust theories also backed many other oligarchic shifts in +public opinion. For example, the idea that taxation is theft, that wealth is +a sign of virtue, and so on — all of these theories meshed to form a +coherent ideology that elevated inequality to a virtue. +

+ Today, many fear that machine learning allows surveillance capitalism to +sell “Bork-as-a-Service,” at internet speeds, so that you can +contract a machine-learning company to engineer rapid +shifts in public sentiment without needing the capital to sustain a +multipronged, multigenerational project working at the local, state, +national, and global levels in business, law, and philosophy. I do not +believe that such a project is plausible, though I agree that this is +basically what the platforms claim to be selling. They’re just lying about +it. Big Tech lies all the time, including in their +sales literature. +

+ The idea that tech forms “natural monopolies” (monopolies that +are the inevitable result of the realities of an industry, such as the +monopolies that accrue the first company to run long-haul phone lines or +rail lines) is belied by tech’s own history: In the absence of +anti-competitive tactics, Google was able to unseat AltaVista and Yahoo; +Facebook was able to head off Myspace. There are some advantages to +gathering mountains of data, but those mountains of data also have +disadvantages: liability (from leaking), diminishing returns (from old +data), and institutional inertia (big companies, like science, progress one +funeral at a time). +

+ Indeed, the birth of the web saw a mass-extinction event for the existing +giant, wildly profitable proprietary technologies that had capital, network +effects, and walls and moats surrounding their businesses. The web showed +that when a new industry is built around a protocol, rather than a product, +the combined might of everyone who uses the protocol to reach their +customers or users or communities outweighs even the most massive +products. CompuServe, AOL, MSN, and a host of other proprietary walled +gardens learned this lesson the hard way: Each believed it could stay +separate from the web, offering “curation” and a guarantee of +consistency and quality instead of the chaos of an open system. Each was +wrong and ended up being absorbed into the public web. +

+ Yes, tech is heavily monopolized and is now closely associated with industry +concentration, but this has more to do with a matter of timing than its +intrinsically monopolistic tendencies. Tech was born at the moment that +antitrust enforcement was being dismantled, and tech fell into exactly the +same pathologies that antitrust was supposed to guard against. To a first +approximation, it is reasonable to assume that tech’s monopolies are the +result of a lack of anti-monopoly action and not the much-touted unique +characteristics of tech, such as network effects, first-mover advantage, and +so on. +

+ In support of this thesis, I offer the concentration that every +other industry has undergone over the same period. From +professional wrestling to consumer packaged goods to commercial property +leasing to banking to sea freight to oil to record labels to newspaper +ownership to theme parks, every industry has undergone +a massive shift toward concentration. There’s no obvious network effects or +first-mover advantage at play in these industries. However, in every case, +these industries attained their concentrated status through tactics that +were prohibited before Bork’s triumph: merging with major competitors, +buying out innovative new market entrants, horizontal and vertical +integration, and a suite of anti-competitive tactics that were once illegal +but are not any longer. +

+ Again: When you change the laws intended to prevent monopolies and then +monopolies form in exactly the way the law was supposed to prevent, it is +reasonable to suppose that these facts are related. Tech’s concentration +can be readily explained without recourse to radical theories of network +effects — but only if you’re willing to indict unregulated markets as +tending toward monopoly. Just as a lifelong smoker can give you a hundred +reasons why their smoking didn’t cause their cancer (“It was the +environmental toxins”), true believers in unregulated markets have a +whole suite of unconvincing explanations for monopoly in tech that leave +capitalism intact. +

Steering with the windshield wipers

+ It’s been 40 years since Bork’s project to rehabilitate monopolies achieved +liftoff, and that is a generation and a half, which is plenty of time to +take a common idea and make it seem outlandish and vice versa. Before the +1940s, affluent Americans dressed their baby boys in pink while baby girls +wore blue (a “delicate and dainty” color). While gendered +colors are obviously totally arbitrary, many still greet this news with +amazement and find it hard to imagine a time when pink connoted masculinity. +

+ After 40 years of studiously ignoring antitrust analysis and enforcement, +it’s not surprising that we’ve all but forgotten that antitrust exists, that +in living memory, growth through mergers and acquisitions were largely +prohibited under law, that market-cornering strategies like vertical +integration could land a company in court. +

+ Antitrust is a market society’s steering wheel, the control of first resort +to keep would-be masters of the universe in their lanes. But Bork and his +cohort ripped out our steering wheel 40 years ago. The car is still +barreling along, and so we’re yanking as hard as we can on all the +other controls in the car as well as desperately +flapping the doors and rolling the windows up and down in the hopes that one +of these other controls can be repurposed to let us choose where we’re +heading before we careen off a cliff. +

+ It’s like a 1960s science-fiction plot come to life: People stuck in a +“generation ship,” plying its way across the stars, a ship once +piloted by their ancestors; and now, after a great cataclysm, the ship’s +crew have forgotten that they’re in a ship at all and no longer remember +where the control room is. Adrift, the ship is racing toward its extinction, +and unless we can seize the controls and execute emergency course +correction, we’re all headed for a fiery death in the heart of a sun. +

Surveillance still matters

+ None of this is to minimize the problems with surveillance. Surveillance +matters, and Big Tech’s use of surveillance is an +existential risk to our species, but that’s not because surveillance and +machine learning rob us of our free will. +

+ Surveillance has become much more efficient thanks to +Big Tech. In 1989, the Stasi — the East German secret police — had the whole +country under surveillance, a massive undertaking that recruited one out of +every 60 people to serve as an informant or intelligence operative. +

+ Today, we know that the NSA is spying on a significant fraction of the +entire world’s population, and its ratio of surveillance operatives to the +surveilled is more like 1:10,000 (that’s probably on the low side since it +assumes that every American with top-secret clearance is working for the NSA +on this project — we don’t know how many of those cleared people are +involved in NSA spying, but it’s definitely not all of them). +

+ How did the ratio of surveillable citizens expand from 1:60 to 1:10,000 in +less than 30 years? It’s thanks to Big Tech. Our devices and services gather +most of the data that the NSA mines for its surveillance project. We pay for +these devices and the services they connect to, and then we painstakingly +perform the data-entry tasks associated with logging facts about our lives, +opinions, and preferences. This mass surveillance project has been largely +useless for fighting terrorism: The NSA can only +point to a single minor success story in which it used its data +collection program to foil an attempt by a U.S. resident to wire a few +thousand dollars to an overseas terror group. It’s ineffective for much the +same reason that commercial surveillance projects are largely ineffective at +targeting advertising: The people who want to commit acts of terror, like +people who want to buy a refrigerator, are extremely rare. If you’re trying +to detect a phenomenon whose base rate is one in a million with an +instrument whose accuracy is only 99%, then every true positive will come at +the cost of 9,999 false positives. +

+ Let me explain that again: If one in a million people is a terrorist, then +there will only be about one terrorist in a random sample of one million +people. If your test for detecting terrorists is 99% accurate, it will +identify 10,000 terrorists in your million-person sample (1% of one million +is 10,000). For every true positive, you’ll get 9,999 false positives. +

+ In reality, the accuracy of algorithmic terrorism detection falls far short +of the 99% mark, as does refrigerator ad targeting. The difference is that +being falsely accused of wanting to buy a fridge is a minor nuisance while +being falsely accused of planning a terror attack can destroy your life and +the lives of everyone you love. +

+ Mass state surveillance is only feasible because of surveillance capitalism +and its extremely low-yield ad-targeting systems, which require a constant +feed of personal data to remain barely viable. Surveillance capitalism’s +primary failure mode is mistargeted ads while mass state surveillance’s +primary failure mode is grotesque human rights abuses, tending toward +totalitarianism. +

+ State surveillance is no mere parasite on Big Tech, sucking up its data and +giving nothing in return. In truth, the two are symbiotes: Big Tech sucks up +our data for spy agencies, and spy agencies ensure that governments don’t +limit Big Tech’s activities so severely that it would no longer serve the +spy agencies’ needs. There is no firm distinction between state surveillance +and surveillance capitalism; they are dependent on one another. +

+ To see this at work today, look no further than Amazon’s home surveillance +device, the Ring doorbell, and its associated app, Neighbors. Ring — a +product that Amazon acquired and did not develop in house — makes a +camera-enabled doorbell that streams footage from your front door to your +mobile device. The Neighbors app allows you to form a neighborhood-wide +surveillance grid with your fellow Ring owners through which you can share +clips of “suspicious characters.” If you’re thinking that this +sounds like a recipe for letting curtain-twitching racists supercharge their +suspicions of people with brown skin who walk down their blocks, you’re +right. Ring has become a de facto, +off-the-books arm of the police without any of the pesky oversight or rules. +

+ In mid-2019, a series of public records requests revealed that Amazon had +struck confidential deals with more than 400 local law enforcement agencies +through which the agencies would promote Ring and Neighbors and in exchange +get access to footage from Ring cameras. In theory, cops would need to +request this footage through Amazon (and internal documents reveal that +Amazon devotes substantial resources to coaching cops on how to spin a +convincing story when doing so), but in practice, when a Ring customer turns +down a police request, Amazon only requires the agency to formally request +the footage from the company, which it will then produce. +

+ Ring and law enforcement have found many ways to intertwine their +activities. Ring strikes secret deals to acquire real-time access to 911 +dispatch and then streams alarming crime reports to Neighbors users, which +serve as convincers for anyone who’s contemplating a surveillance doorbell +but isn’t sure whether their neighborhood is dangerous enough to warrant it. +

+ The more the cops buzz-market the surveillance capitalist Ring, the more +surveillance capability the state gets. Cops who rely on private entities +for law-enforcement roles then brief against any controls on the deployment +of that technology while the companies return the favor by lobbying against +rules requiring public oversight of police surveillance technology. The more +the cops rely on Ring and Neighbors, the harder it will be to pass laws to +curb them. The fewer laws there are against them, the more the cops will +rely on them. +

Dignity and sanctuary

+ But even if we could exercise democratic control over our states and force +them to stop raiding surveillance capitalism’s reservoirs of behavioral +data, surveillance capitalism would still harm us. +

+ This is an area where Zuboff shines. Her chapter on “sanctuary” +— the feeling of being unobserved — is a beautiful hymn to introspection, +calmness, mindfulness, and tranquility. +

+ When you are watched, something changes. Anyone who has ever raised a child +knows this. You might look up from your book (or more realistically, from +your phone) and catch your child in a moment of profound realization and +growth, a moment where they are learning something that is right at the edge +of their abilities, requiring their entire ferocious concentration. For a +moment, you’re transfixed, watching that rare and beautiful moment of focus +playing out before your eyes, and then your child looks up and sees you +seeing them, and the moment collapses. To grow, you need to be and expose +your authentic self, and in that moment, you are vulnerable like a hermit +crab scuttling from one shell to the next. The tender, unprotected tissues +you expose in that moment are too delicate to reveal in the presence of +another, even someone you trust as implicitly as a child trusts their +parent. +

+ In the digital age, our authentic selves are inextricably tied to our +digital lives. Your search history is a running ledger of the questions +you’ve pondered. Your location history is a record of the places you’ve +sought out and the experiences you’ve had there. Your social graph reveals +the different facets of your identity, the people you’ve connected with. +

+ To be observed in these activities is to lose the sanctuary of your +authentic self. +

+ There’s another way in which surveillance capitalism robs us of our capacity +to be our authentic selves: by making us anxious. Surveillance capitalism +isn’t really a mind-control ray, but you don’t need a mind-control ray to +make someone anxious. After all, another word for anxiety is agitation, and +to make someone experience agitation, you need merely to agitate them. To +poke them and prod them and beep at them and buzz at them and bombard them +on an intermittent schedule that is just random enough that our limbic +systems never quite become inured to it. +

+ Our devices and services are “general purpose” in that they can +connect anything or anyone to anything or anyone else and that they can run +any program that can be written. This means that the distraction rectangles +in our pockets hold our most precious moments with our most beloved people +and their most urgent or time-sensitive communications (from “running +late can you get the kid?” to “doctor gave me bad news and I +need to talk to you RIGHT NOW”) as well as ads for refrigerators and +recruiting messages from Nazis. +

+ All day and all night, our pockets buzz, shattering our concentration and +tearing apart the fragile webs of connection we spin as we think through +difficult ideas. If you locked someone in a cell and agitated them like +this, we’d call it “sleep deprivation torture,” and it would be +a war crime under +the Geneva Conventions. +

Afflicting the afflicted

+ The effects of surveillance on our ability to be our authentic selves are +not equal for all people. Some of us are lucky enough to live in a time and +place in which all the most important facts of our lives are widely and +roundly socially acceptable and can be publicly displayed without the risk +of social consequence. +

+ But for many of us, this is not true. Recall that in living memory, many of +the ways of being that we think of as socially acceptable today were once +cause for dire social sanction or even imprisonment. If you are 65 years +old, you have lived through a time in which people living in “free +societies” could be imprisoned or sanctioned for engaging in +homosexual activity, for falling in love with a person whose skin was a +different color than their own, or for smoking weed. +

+ Today, these activities aren’t just decriminalized in much of the world, +they’re considered normal, and the fallen prohibitions are viewed as +shameful, regrettable relics of the past. +

+ How did we get from prohibition to normalization? Through private, personal +activity: People who were secretly gay or secret pot-smokers or who secretly +loved someone with a different skin color were vulnerable to retaliation if +they made their true selves known and were limited in how much they could +advocate for their own right to exist in the world and be true to +themselves. But because there was a private sphere, these people could form +alliances with their friends and loved ones who did not share their +disfavored traits by having private conversations in which they came out, +disclosing their true selves to the people around them and bringing them to +their cause one conversation at a time. +

+ The right to choose the time and manner of these conversations was key to +their success. It’s one thing to come out to your dad while you’re on a +fishing trip away from the world and another thing entirely to blurt it out +over the Christmas dinner table while your racist Facebook uncle is there to +make a scene. +

+ Without a private sphere, there’s a chance that none of these changes would +have come to pass and that the people who benefited from these changes would +have either faced social sanction for coming out to a hostile world or would +have never been able to reveal their true selves to the people they love. +

+ The corollary is that, unless you think that our society has attained social +perfection — that your grandchildren in 50 years will ask you to tell them +the story of how, in 2020, every injustice had been righted and no further +change had to be made — then you should expect that right now, at this +minute, there are people you love, whose happiness is key to your own, who +have a secret in their hearts that stops them from ever being their +authentic selves with you. These people are sorrowing and will go to their +graves with that secret sorrow in their hearts, and the source of that +sorrow will be the falsity of their relationship to you. +

+ A private realm is necessary for human progress. +

Any data you collect and retain will eventually leak

+ The lack of a private life can rob vulnerable people of the chance to be +their authentic selves and constrain our actions by depriving us of +sanctuary, but there is another risk that is borne by everyone, not just +people with a secret: crime. +

+ Personally identifying information is of very limited use for the purpose of +controlling peoples’ minds, but identity theft — really a catchall term for +a whole constellation of terrible criminal activities that can destroy your +finances, compromise your personal integrity, ruin your reputation, or even +expose you to physical danger — thrives on it. +

+ Attackers are not limited to using data from one breached source, +either. Multiple services have suffered breaches that exposed names, +addresses, phone numbers, passwords, sexual tastes, school grades, work +performance, brushes with the criminal justice system, family details, +genetic information, fingerprints and other biometrics, reading habits, +search histories, literary tastes, pseudonymous identities, and other +sensitive information. Attackers can merge data from these different +breaches to build up extremely detailed dossiers on random subjects and then +use different parts of the data for different criminal purposes. +

+ For example, attackers can use leaked username and password combinations to +hijack whole fleets of commercial vehicles that have +been fitted with anti-theft GPS trackers and immobilizers or to +hijack baby monitors in order to terrorize +toddlers with the audio tracks from pornography. Attackers use +leaked data to trick phone companies into giving them your phone number, +then they intercept SMS-based two-factor authentication codes in order to +take over your email, bank account, and/or cryptocurrency wallets. +

+ Attackers are endlessly inventive in the pursuit of creative ways to +weaponize leaked data. One common use of leaked data is to penetrate +companies in order to access more data. +

+ Like spies, online fraudsters are totally dependent on companies +over-collecting and over-retaining our data. Spy agencies sometimes pay +companies for access to their data or intimidate them into giving it up, but +sometimes they work just like criminals do — by sneaking data out of +companies’ databases. +

+ The over-collection of data has a host of terrible social consequences, from +the erosion of our authentic selves to the undermining of social progress, +from state surveillance to an epidemic of online crime. Commercial +surveillance is also a boon to people running influence campaigns, but +that’s the least of our troubles. +

Critical tech exceptionalism is still tech exceptionalism

+ Big Tech has long practiced technology exceptionalism: the idea that it +should not be subject to the mundane laws and norms of +“meatspace.” Mottoes like Facebook’s “move fast and break +things” attracted justifiable scorn of the companies’ self-serving +rhetoric. +

+ Tech exceptionalism got us all into a lot of trouble, so it’s ironic and +distressing to see Big Tech’s critics committing the same sin. +

+ Big Tech is not a “rogue capitalism” that cannot be cured +through the traditional anti-monopoly remedies of trustbusting (forcing +companies to divest of competitors they have acquired) and bans on mergers +to monopoly and other anti-competitive tactics. Big Tech does not have the +power to use machine learning to influence our behavior so thoroughly that +markets lose the ability to punish bad actors and reward superior +competitors. Big Tech has no rule-writing mind-control ray that necessitates +ditching our old toolbox. +

+ The thing is, people have been claiming to have perfected mind-control rays +for centuries, and every time, it turned out to be a con — though sometimes +the con artists were also conning themselves. +

+ For generations, the advertising industry has been steadily improving its +ability to sell advertising services to businesses while only making +marginal gains in selling those businesses’ products to prospective +customers. John Wanamaker’s lament that “50% of my advertising budget +is wasted, I just don’t know which 50%” is a testament to the triumph +of ad executives, who successfully convinced Wanamaker +that only half of the money he spent went to waste. +

+ The tech industry has made enormous improvements in the science of +convincing businesses that they’re good at advertising while their actual +improvements to advertising — as opposed to targeting — have been pretty +ho-hum. The vogue for machine learning — and the mystical invocation of +“artificial intelligence” as a synonym for straightforward +statistical inference techniques — has greatly boosted the efficacy of Big +Tech’s sales pitch as marketers have exploited potential customers’ lack of +technical sophistication to get away with breathtaking acts of overpromising +and underdelivering. +

+ It’s tempting to think that if businesses are willing to pour billions into +a venture that the venture must be a good one. Yet there are plenty of times +when this rule of thumb has led us astray. For example, it’s virtually +unheard of for managed investment funds to outperform simple index funds, +and investors who put their money into the hands of expert money managers +overwhelmingly fare worse than those who entrust their savings to index +funds. But managed funds still account for the majority of the money +invested in the markets, and they are patronized by some of the richest, +most sophisticated investors in the world. Their vote of confidence in an +underperforming sector is a parable about the role of luck in wealth +accumulation, not a sign that managed funds are a good buy. +

+ The claims of Big Tech’s mind-control system are full of tells that the +enterprise is a con. For example, the +reliance on the “Big Five” personality traits as a +primary means of influencing people even though the “Big Five” +theory is unsupported by any large-scale, peer-reviewed studies and is +mostly +the realm of marketing hucksters and pop psych. +

+ Big Tech’s promotional materials also claim that their algorithms can +accurately perform “sentiment analysis” or detect peoples’ +moods based on their “microexpressions,” but these +are marketing claims, not scientific ones. These methods are largely +untested by independent scientific experts, and where they have been tested, +they’ve been found sorely wanting. Microexpressions are particularly +suspect as the companies that specialize in training people to detect them +have +been shown to underperform relative to random chance. +

+ Big Tech has been so good at marketing its own supposed superpowers that +it’s easy to believe that they can market everything else with similar +acumen, but it’s a mistake to believe the hype. Any statement a company +makes about the quality of its products is clearly not impartial. The fact +that we distrust all the things that Big Tech says about its data handling, +compliance with privacy laws, etc., is only reasonable — but why on Earth +would we treat Big Tech’s marketing literature as the gospel truth? Big Tech +lies about just about everything, including how well +its machine-learning fueled persuasion systems work. +

+ That skepticism should infuse all of our evaluations of Big Tech and its +supposed abilities, including our perusal of its patents. Zuboff vests these +patents with enormous significance, pointing out that Google claimed +extensive new persuasion capabilities in its patent +filings. These claims are doubly suspect: first, because they are so +self-serving, and second, because the patent itself is so notoriously an +invitation to exaggeration. +

+ Patent applications take the form of a series of claims and range from broad +to narrow. A typical patent starts out by claiming that its authors have +invented a method or system for doing every conceivable thing that anyone +might do, ever, with any tool or device. Then it narrows that claim in +successive stages until we get to the actual “invention” that +is the true subject of the patent. The hope is that the patent examiner — +who is almost certainly overworked and underinformed — will miss the fact +that some or all of these claims are ridiculous, or at least suspect, and +grant the patent’s broader claims. Patents for unpatentable things are still +incredibly useful because they can be wielded against competitors who might +license that patent or steer clear of its claims rather than endure the +lengthy, expensive process of contesting it. +

+ What’s more, software patents are routinely granted even though the filer +doesn’t have any evidence that they can do the thing claimed by the +patent. That is, you can patent an “invention” that you haven’t +actually made and that you don’t know how to make. +

+ With these considerations in hand, it becomes obvious that the fact that a +Big Tech company has patented what it says is an +effective mind-control ray is largely irrelevant to whether Big Tech can in +fact control our minds. +

+ Big Tech collects our data for many reasons, including the diminishing +returns on existing stores of data. But many tech companies also collect +data out of a mistaken tech exceptionalist belief in the network effects of +data. Network effects occur when each new user in a system increases its +value. The classic example is fax machines: A single fax machine is of no +use, two fax machines are of limited use, but every new fax machine that’s +put to use after the first doubles the number of possible fax-to-fax links. +

+ Data mined for predictive systems doesn’t necessarily produce these +dividends. Think of Netflix: The predictive value of the data mined from a +million English-speaking Netflix viewers is hardly improved by the addition +of one more user’s viewing data. Most of the data Netflix acquires after +that first minimum viable sample duplicates existing data and produces only +minimal gains. Meanwhile, retraining models with new data gets progressively +more expensive as the number of data points increases, and manual tasks like +labeling and validating data do not get cheaper at scale. +

+ Businesses pursue fads to the detriment of their profits all the time, +especially when the businesses and their investors are not motivated by the +prospect of becoming profitable but rather by the prospect of being acquired +by a Big Tech giant or by having an IPO. For these firms, ticking faddish +boxes like “collects as much data as possible” might realize a +bigger return on investment than “collects a business-appropriate +quantity of data.” +

+ This is another harm of tech exceptionalism: The belief that more data +always produces more profits in the form of more insights that can be +translated into better mind-control rays drives firms to over-collect and +over-retain data beyond all rationality. And since the firms are behaving +irrationally, a good number of them will go out of business and become ghost +ships whose cargo holds are stuffed full of data that can harm people in +myriad ways — but which no one is responsible for antey longer. Even if the +companies don’t go under, the data they collect is maintained behind the +minimum viable security — just enough security to keep the company viable +while it waits to get bought out by a tech giant, an amount calculated to +spend not one penny more than is necessary on protecting data. +

How monopolies, not mind control, drive surveillance capitalism: The +Snapchat story

+ For the first decade of its existence, Facebook competed with the social +media giants of the day (Myspace, Orkut, etc.) by presenting itself as the +pro-privacy alternative. Indeed, Facebook justified its walled garden — +which let users bring in data from the web but blocked web services like +Google Search from indexing and caching Facebook pages — as a pro-privacy +measure that protected users from the surveillance-happy winners of the +social media wars like Myspace. +

+ Despite frequent promises that it would never collect or analyze its users’ +data, Facebook periodically created initiatives that did just that, like the +creepy, ham-fisted Beacon tool, which spied on you as you moved around the +web and then added your online activities to your public timeline, allowing +your friends to monitor your browsing habits. Beacon sparked a user +revolt. Every time, Facebook backed off from its surveillance initiative, +but not all the way; inevitably, the new Facebook would be more surveilling +than the old Facebook, though not quite as surveilling as the intermediate +Facebook following the launch of the new product or service. +

+ The pace at which Facebook ramped up its surveillance efforts seems to have +been set by Facebook’s competitive landscape. The more competitors Facebook +had, the better it behaved. Every time a major competitor foundered, +Facebook’s behavior got +markedly worse. +

+ All the while, Facebook was prodigiously acquiring companies, including a +company called Onavo. Nominally, Onavo made a battery-monitoring mobile +app. But the permissions that Onavo required were so expansive that the app +was able to gather fine-grained telemetry on everything users did with their +phones, including which apps they used and how they were using them. +

+ Through Onavo, Facebook discovered that it was losing market share to +Snapchat, an app that — like Facebook a decade before — billed itself as the +pro-privacy alternative to the status quo. Through Onavo, Facebook was able +to mine data from the devices of Snapchat users, including both current and +former Snapchat users. This spurred Facebook to acquire Instagram — some +features of which competed with Snapchat — and then allowed Facebook to +fine-tune Instagram’s features and sales pitch to erode Snapchat’s gains and +ensure that Facebook would not have to face the kinds of competitive +pressures it had earlier inflicted on Myspace and Orkut. +

+ The story of how Facebook crushed Snapchat reveals the relationship between +monopoly and surveillance capitalism. Facebook combined surveillance with +lax antitrust enforcement to spot the competitive threat of Snapchat on its +horizon and then take decisive action against it. Facebook’s surveillance +capitalism let it avert competitive pressure with anti-competitive +tactics. Facebook users still want privacy — Facebook hasn’t used +surveillance to brainwash them out of it — but they can’t get it because +Facebook’s surveillance lets it destroy any hope of a rival service emerging +that competes on privacy features. +

A monopoly over your friends

+ A decentralization movement has tried to erode the dominance of Facebook and +other Big Tech companies by fielding “indieweb” alternatives — +Mastodon as a Twitter alternative, Diaspora as a Facebook alternative, +etc. — but these efforts have failed to attain any kind of liftoff. +

+ Fundamentally, each of these services is hamstrung by the same problem: +Every potential user for a Facebook or Twitter alternative has to convince +all their friends to follow them to a decentralized web alternative in order +to continue to realize the benefit of social media. For many of us, the only +reason to have a Facebook account is that our friends have Facebook +accounts, and the reason they have Facebook accounts is that +we have Facebook accounts. +

+ All of this has conspired to make Facebook — and other dominant platforms — +into “kill zones” that investors will not fund new entrants +for. +

+ And yet, all of today’s tech giants came into existence despite the +entrenched advantage of the companies that came before them. To understand +how that happened, you have to understand both interoperability and +adversarial interoperability. +

+ The hard problem of our species is coordination. +

+ “Interoperability” is the ability of two technologies to work +with one another: Anyone can make an LP that will play on any record player, +anyone can make a filter you can install in your stove’s extractor fan, +anyone can make gasoline for your car, anyone can make a USB phone charger +that fits in your car’s cigarette lighter receptacle, anyone can make a +light bulb that works in your light socket, anyone can make bread that will +toast in your toaster. +

+ Interoperability is often a source of innovation and consumer benefit: Apple +made the first commercially successful PC, but millions of independent +software vendors made interoperable programs that ran on the Apple II +Plus. The simple analog antenna inputs on the back of TVs first allowed +cable operators to connect directly to TVs, then they allowed game console +companies and then personal computer companies to use standard televisions +as displays. Standard RJ-11 telephone jacks allowed for the production of +phones from a variety of vendors in a variety of forms, from the free +football-shaped phone that came with a Sports +Illustrated subscription to business phones with speakers, hold +functions, and so on and then answering machines and finally modems, paving +the way for the internet revolution. +

+ “Interoperability” is often used interchangeably with +“standardization,” which is the process when manufacturers and +other stakeholders hammer out a set of agreed-upon rules for implementing a +technology, such as the electrical plug on your wall, the CAN bus used by +your car’s computer systems, or the HTML instructions that your browser +interprets. +

+ But interoperability doesn’t require standardization — indeed, +standardization often proceeds from the chaos of ad hoc interoperability +measures. The inventor of the cigarette-lighter USB charger didn’t need to +get permission from car manufacturers or even the manufacturers of the +dashboard lighter subcomponent. The automakers didn’t take any +countermeasures to prevent the use of these aftermarket accessories by their +customers, but they also didn’t do anything to make life easier for the +chargers’ manufacturers. This is a kind of “neutral +interoperability.” +

+ Beyond neutral interoperability, there is “adversarial +interoperability.” That’s when a manufacturer makes a product that +interoperates with another manufacturer’s product despite the +second manufacturer’s objections and even if that means +bypassing a security system designed to prevent interoperability. +

+ Probably the most familiar form of adversarial interoperability is +third-party printer ink. Printer manufacturers claim that they sell printers +below cost and that the only way they can recoup the losses they incur is by +charging high markups on ink. To prevent the owners of printers from buying +ink elsewhere, the printer companies deploy a suite of anti-customer +security systems that detect and reject both refilled and third-party +cartridges. +

+ Owners of printers take the position that HP and Epson and Brother are not +charities and that customers for their wares have no obligation to help them +survive, and so if the companies choose to sell their products at a loss, +that’s their foolish choice and their consequences to live with. Likewise, +competitors who make ink or refill kits observe that they don’t owe printer +companies anything, and their erosion of printer companies’ margins are the +printer companies’ problems, not their competitors’. After all, the printer +companies shed no tears when they drive a refiller out of business, so why +should the refillers concern themselves with the economic fortunes of the +printer companies? +

+ Adversarial interoperability has played an outsized role in the history of +the tech industry: from the founding of the “alt.*” Usenet +hierarchy (which was started against the wishes of Usenet’s maintainers and +which grew to be bigger than all of Usenet combined) to the browser wars +(when Netscape and Microsoft devoted massive engineering efforts to making +their browsers incompatible with the other’s special commands and +peccadilloes) to Facebook (whose success was built in part by helping its +new users stay in touch with friends they’d left behind on Myspace because +Facebook supplied them with a tool that scraped waiting messages from +Myspace and imported them into Facebook, effectively creating an +Facebook-based Myspace reader). +

+ Today, incumbency is seen as an unassailable advantage. Facebook is where +all of your friends are, so no one can start a Facebook competitor. But +adversarial compatibility reverses the competitive advantage: If you were +allowed to compete with Facebook by providing a tool that imported all your +users’ waiting Facebook messages into an environment that competed on lines +that Facebook couldn’t cross, like eliminating surveillance and ads, then +Facebook would be at a huge disadvantage. It would have assembled all +possible ex-Facebook users into a single, easy-to-find service; it would +have educated them on how a Facebook-like service worked and what its +potential benefits were; and it would have provided an easy means for +disgruntled Facebook users to tell their friends where they might expect +better treatment. +

+ Adversarial interoperability was once the norm and a key contributor to the +dynamic, vibrant tech scene, but now it is stuck behind a thicket of laws +and regulations that add legal risks to the tried-and-true tactics of +adversarial interoperability. New rules and new interpretations of existing +rules mean that a would-be adversarial interoperator needs to steer clear of +claims under copyright, terms of service, trade secrecy, tortious +interference, and patent. +

+ In the absence of a competitive market, lawmakers have resorted to assigning +expensive, state-like duties to Big Tech firms, such as automatically +filtering user contributions for copyright infringement or terrorist and +extremist content or detecting and preventing harassment in real time or +controlling access to sexual material. +

+ These measures put a floor under how small we can make Big Tech because only +the very largest companies can afford the humans and automated filters +needed to perform these duties. +

+ But that’s not the only way in which making platforms responsible for +policing their users undermines competition. A platform that is expected to +police its users’ conduct must prevent many vital adversarial +interoperability techniques lest these subvert its policing measures. For +example, if someone using a Twitter replacement like Mastodon is able to +push messages into Twitter and read messages out of Twitter, they could +avoid being caught by automated systems that detect and prevent harassment +(such as systems that use the timing of messages or IP-based rules to make +guesses about whether someone is a harasser). +

+ To the extent that we are willing to let Big Tech police itself — rather +than making Big Tech small enough that users can leave bad platforms for +better ones and small enough that a regulation that simply puts a platform +out of business will not destroy billions of users’ access to their +communities and data — we build the case that Big Tech should be able to +block its competitors and make it easier for Big Tech to demand legal +enforcement tools to ban and punish attempts at adversarial +interoperability. +

+ Ultimately, we can try to fix Big Tech by making it responsible for bad acts +by its users, or we can try to fix the internet by cutting Big Tech down to +size. But we can’t do both. To replace today’s giant products with +pluralistic protocols, we need to clear the legal thicket that prevents +adversarial interoperability so that tomorrow’s nimble, personal, +small-scale products can federate themselves with giants like Facebook, +allowing the users who’ve left to continue to communicate with users who +haven’t left yet, reaching tendrils over Facebook’s garden wall that +Facebook’s trapped users can use to scale the walls and escape to the +global, open web. +

Fake news is an epistemological crisis

+ Tech is not the only industry that has undergone massive concentration since +the Reagan era. Virtually every major industry — from oil to newspapers to +meatpacking to sea freight to eyewear to online pornography — has become a +clubby oligarchy that just a few players dominate. +

+ At the same time, every industry has become something of a tech industry as +general-purpose computers and general-purpose networks and the promise of +efficiencies through data-driven analysis infuse every device, process, and +firm with tech. +

+ This phenomenon of industrial concentration is part of a wider story about +wealth concentration overall as a smaller and smaller number of people own +more and more of our world. This concentration of both wealth and industries +means that our political outcomes are increasingly beholden to the parochial +interests of the people and companies with all the money. +

+ That means that whenever a regulator asks a question with an obvious, +empirical answer (“Are humans causing climate change?” or +“Should we let companies conduct commercial mass surveillance?” +or “Does society benefit from allowing network neutrality +violations?”), the answer that comes out is only correct if that +correctness meets with the approval of rich people and the industries that +made them so wealthy. +

+ Rich people have always played an outsized role in politics and more so +since the Supreme Court’s Citizens United decision +eliminated key controls over political spending. Widening inequality and +wealth concentration means that the very richest people are now a lot richer +and can afford to spend a lot more money on political projects than ever +before. Think of the Koch brothers or George Soros or Bill Gates. +

+ But the policy distortions of rich individuals pale in comparison to the +policy distortions that concentrated industries are capable of. The +companies in highly concentrated industries are much more profitable than +companies in competitive industries — no competition means not having to +reduce prices or improve quality to win customers — leaving them with bigger +capital surpluses to spend on lobbying. +

+ Concentrated industries also find it easier to collaborate on policy +objectives than competitive ones. When all the top execs from your industry +can fit around a single boardroom table, they often do. And +when they do, they can forge a consensus position on +regulation. +

+ Rising through the ranks in a concentrated industry generally means working +at two or three of the big companies. When there are only relatively few +companies in a given industry, each company has a more ossified executive +rank, leaving ambitious execs with fewer paths to higher positions unless +they are recruited to a rival. This means that the top execs in concentrated +industries are likely to have been colleagues at some point and socialize in +the same circles — connected through social ties or, say, serving as +trustees for each others’ estates. These tight social bonds foster a +collegial, rather than competitive, attitude. +

+ Highly concentrated industries also present a regulatory conundrum. When an +industry is dominated by just four or five companies, the only people who +are likely to truly understand the industry’s practices are its veteran +executives. This means that top regulators are often former execs of the +companies they are supposed to be regulating. These turns in government are +often tacitly understood to be leaves of absence from industry, with former +employers welcoming their erstwhile watchdogs back into their executive +ranks once their terms have expired. +

+ All this is to say that the tight social bonds, small number of firms, and +regulatory capture of concentrated industries give the companies that +comprise them the power to dictate many, if not all, of the regulations that +bind them. +

+ This is increasingly obvious. Whether it’s payday lenders winning +the right to practice predatory lending or Apple winning +the right to decide who can fix your phone or Google and Facebook +winning the right to breach your private data without suffering meaningful +consequences or victories for pipeline companies or impunity for opioid +manufacturers or massive tax subsidies for incredibly profitable dominant +businesses, it’s increasingly apparent that many of our official, +evidence-based truth-seeking processes are, in fact, auctions for sale to +the highest bidder. +

+ It’s really impossible to overstate what a terrifying prospect this is. We +live in an incredibly high-tech society, and none of us could acquire the +expertise to evaluate every technological proposition that stands between us +and our untimely, horrible deaths. You might devote your life to acquiring +the media literacy to distinguish good scientific journals from corrupt +pay-for-play lookalikes and the statistical literacy to evaluate the quality +of the analysis in the journals as well as the microbiology and epidemiology +knowledge to determine whether you can trust claims about the safety of +vaccines — but that would still leave you unqualified to judge whether the +wiring in your home will give you a lethal shock and +whether your car’s brakes’ software will cause them to fail unpredictably +and whether the hygiene standards at your butcher are +sufficient to keep you from dying after you finish your dinner. +

+ In a world as complex as this one, we have to defer to authorities, and we +keep them honest by making those authorities accountable to us and binding +them with rules to prevent conflicts of interest. We can’t possibly acquire +the expertise to adjudicate conflicting claims about the best way to make +the world safe and prosperous, but we can determine +whether the adjudication process itself is trustworthy. +

+ Right now, it’s obviously not. +

+ The past 40 years of rising inequality and industry concentration, together +with increasingly weak accountability and transparency for expert agencies, +has created an increasingly urgent sense of impending doom, the sense that +there are vast conspiracies afoot that operate with tacit official approval +despite the likelihood they are working to better themselves by ruining the +rest of us. +

+ For example, it’s been decades since Exxon’s own scientists concluded that +its products would render the Earth uninhabitable by humans. And yet those +decades were lost to us, in large part because Exxon lobbied governments and +sowed doubt about the dangers of its products and did so with the +cooperation of many public officials. When the survival of you and everyone +you love is threatened by conspiracies, it’s not unreasonable to start +questioning the things you think you know in an attempt to determine whether +they, too, are the outcome of another conspiracy. +

+ The collapse of the credibility of our systems for divining and upholding +truths has left us in a state of epistemological chaos. Once, most of us +might have assumed that the system was working and that our regulations +reflected our best understanding of the empirical truths of the world as +they were best understood — now we have to find our own experts to help us +sort the true from the false. +

+ If you’re like me, you probably believe that vaccines are safe, but you +(like me) probably also can’t explain the microbiology or statistics. Few of +us have the math skills to review the literature on vaccine safety and +describe why their statistical reasoning is sound. Likewise, few of us can +review the stats in the (now discredited) literature on opioid safety and +explain how those stats were manipulated. Both vaccines and opioids were +embraced by medical authorities, after all, and one is safe while the other +could ruin your life. You’re left with a kind of inchoate constellation of +rules of thumb about which experts you trust to fact-check controversial +claims and then to explain how all those respectable doctors with their +peer-reviewed research on opioid safety were an +aberration and then how you know that the doctors writing about vaccine +safety are not an aberration. +

+ I’m 100% certain that vaccinating is safe and effective, but I’m also at +something of a loss to explain exactly, precisely, why +I believe this, given all the corruption I know about and the many times the +stamp of certainty has turned out to be a parochial lie told to further +enrich the super rich. +

+ Fake news — conspiracy theories, racist ideologies, scientific denialism — +has always been with us. What’s changed today is not the mix of ideas in the +public discourse but the popularity of the worst ideas in that +mix. Conspiracy and denial have skyrocketed in lockstep with the growth of +Big Inequality, which has also tracked the rise of Big Tech and Big Pharma +and Big Wrestling and Big Car and Big Movie Theater and Big Everything Else. +

+ No one can say for certain why this has happened, but the two dominant camps +are idealism (the belief that the people who argue for these conspiracies +have gotten better at explaining them, maybe with the help of +machine-learning tools) or materialism (the ideas have become more +attractive because of material conditions in the world). +

+ I’m a materialist. I’ve been exposed to the arguments of conspiracy +theorists all my life, and I have not experienced any qualitative leap in +the quality of those arguments. +

+ The major difference is in the world, not the arguments. In a time where +actual conspiracies are commonplace, conspiracy theories acquire a ring of +plausibility. +

+ We have always had disagreements about what’s true, but today, we have a +disagreement over how we know whether something is true. This is an +epistemological crisis, not a crisis over belief. It’s a crisis over the +credibility of our truth-seeking exercises, from scientific journals (in an +era where the biggest journal publishers have been caught producing +pay-to-play journals for junk science) to regulations (in an era where +regulators are routinely cycling in and out of business) to education (in an +era where universities are dependent on corporate donations to keep their +lights on). +

+ Targeting — surveillance capitalism — makes it easier to find people who are +undergoing this epistemological crisis, but it doesn’t create the +crisis. For that, you need to look to corruption. +

+ And, conveniently enough, it’s corruption that allows surveillance +capitalism to grow by dismantling monopoly protections, by permitting +reckless collection and retention of personal data, by allowing ads to be +targeted in secret, and by foreclosing on the possibility of going somewhere +else where you might continue to enjoy your friends without subjecting +yourself to commercial surveillance. +

Tech is different

+ I reject both iterations of technological exceptionalism. I reject the idea +that tech is uniquely terrible and led by people who are greedier or worse +than the leaders of other industries, and I reject the idea that tech is so +good — or so intrinsically prone to concentration — that it can’t be blamed +for its present-day monopolistic status. +

+ I think tech is just another industry, albeit one that grew up in the +absence of real monopoly constraints. It may have been first, but it isn’t +the worst nor will it be the last. +

+ But there’s one way in which I am a tech +exceptionalist. I believe that online tools are the key to overcoming +problems that are much more urgent than tech monopolization: climate change, +inequality, misogyny, and discrimination on the basis of race, gender +identity, and other factors. The internet is how we will recruit people to +fight those fights, and how we will coordinate their labor. Tech is not a +substitute for democratic accountability, the rule of law, fairness, or +stability — but it’s a means to achieve these things. +

+ The hard problem of our species is coordination. Everything from climate +change to social change to running a business to making a family work can be +viewed as a collective action problem. +

+ The internet makes it easier than at any time before to find people who want +to work on a project with you — hence the success of free and open-source +software, crowdfunding, and racist terror groups — and easier than ever to +coordinate the work you do. +

+ The internet and the computers we connect to it also possess an exceptional +quality: general-purposeness. The internet is designed to allow any two +parties to communicate any data, using any protocol, without permission from +anyone else. The only production design we have for computers is the +general-purpose, “Turing complete” computer that can run every +program we can express in symbolic logic. +

+ This means that every time someone with a special communications need +invests in infrastructure and techniques to make the internet faster, +cheaper, and more robust, this benefit redounds to everyone else who is +using the internet to communicate. And this also means that every time +someone with a special computing need invests to make computers faster, +cheaper, and more robust, every other computing application is a potential +beneficiary of this work. +

+ For these reasons, every type of communication is gradually absorbed into +the internet, and every type of device — from airplanes to pacemakers — +eventually becomes a computer in a fancy case. +

+ While these considerations don’t preclude regulating networks and computers, +they do call for gravitas and caution when doing so because changes to +regulatory frameworks could ripple out to have unintended consequences in +many, many other domains. +

+ The upshot of this is that our best hope of solving the big coordination +problems — climate change, inequality, etc. — is with free, fair, and open +tech. Our best hope of keeping tech free, fair, and open is to exercise +caution in how we regulate tech and to attend closely to the ways in which +interventions to solve one problem might create problems in other domains. +

Ownership of facts

+ Big Tech has a funny relationship with information. When you’re generating +information — anything from the location data streaming off your mobile +device to the private messages you send to friends on a social network — it +claims the rights to make unlimited use of that data. +

+ But when you have the audacity to turn the tables — to use a tool that +blocks ads or slurps your waiting updates out of a social network and puts +them in another app that lets you set your own priorities and suggestions or +crawls their system to allow you to start a rival business — they claim that +you’re stealing from them. +

+ The thing is, information is a very bad fit for any kind of private property +regime. Property rights are useful for establishing markets that can lead to +the effective development of fallow assets. These markets depend on clear +titles to ensure that the things being bought and sold in them can, in fact, +be bought and sold. +

+ Information rarely has such a clear title. Take phone numbers: There’s +clearly something going wrong when Facebook slurps up millions of users’ +address books and uses the phone numbers it finds in them to plot out social +graphs and fill in missing information about other users. +

+ But the phone numbers Facebook nonconsensually acquires in this transaction +are not the “property” of the users they’re taken from nor do +they belong to the people whose phones ring when you dial those numbers. The +numbers are mere integers, 10 digits in the U.S. and Canada, and they +appear in millions of places, including somewhere deep in pi as well as +numerous other contexts. Giving people ownership titles to integers is an +obviously terrible idea. +

+ Likewise for the facts that Facebook and other commercial surveillance +operators acquire about us, like that we are the children of our parents or +the parents to our children or that we had a conversation with someone else +or went to a public place. These data points can’t be property in the sense +that your house or your shirt is your property because the title to them is +intrinsically muddy: Does your mom own the fact that she is your mother? Do +you? Do both of you? What about your dad — does he own this fact too, or +does he have to license the fact from you (or your mom or both of you) in +order to use this fact? What about the hundreds or thousands of other people +who know these facts? +

+ If you go to a Black Lives Matter demonstration, do the other demonstrators +need your permission to post their photos from the event? The online fights +over when and +how to post photos from demonstrations reveal a nuanced, complex +issue that cannot be easily hand-waved away by giving one party a property +right that everyone else in the mix has to respect. +

+ The fact that information isn’t a good fit with property and markets doesn’t +mean that it’s not valuable. Babies aren’t property, but they’re inarguably +valuable. In fact, we have a whole set of rules just for babies as well as a +subset of those rules that apply to humans more generally. Someone who +argues that babies won’t be truly valuable until they can be bought and sold +like loaves of bread would be instantly and rightfully condemned as a +monster. +

+ It’s tempting to reach for the property hammer when Big Tech treats your +information like a nail — not least because Big Tech are such prolific +abusers of property hammers when it comes to their +information. But this is a mistake. If we allow markets to dictate the use +of our information, then we’ll find that we’re sellers in a buyers’ market +where the Big Tech monopolies set a price for our data that is so low as to +be insignificant or, more likely, set at a nonnegotiable price of zero in a +click-through agreement that you don’t have the opportunity to modify. +

+ Meanwhile, establishing property rights over information will create +insurmountable barriers to independent data processing. Imagine that we +require a license to be negotiated when a translated document is compared +with its original, something Google has done and continues to do billions of +times to train its automated language translation tools. Google can afford +this, but independent third parties cannot. Google can staff a clearances +department to negotiate one-time payments to the likes of the EU (one of the +major repositories of translated documents) while independent watchdogs +wanting to verify that the translations are well-prepared, or to root out +bias in translations, will find themselves needing a staffed-up legal +department and millions for licenses before they can even get started. +

+ The same goes for things like search indexes of the web or photos of +peoples’ houses, which have become contentious thanks to Google’s Street +View project. Whatever problems may exist with Google’s photographing of +street scenes, resolving them by letting people decide who can take pictures +of the facades of their homes from a public street will surely create even +worse ones. Think of how street photography is important for newsgathering — +including informal newsgathering, like photographing abuses of authority — +and how being able to document housing and street life are important for +contesting eminent domain, advocating for social aid, reporting planning and +zoning violations, documenting discriminatory and unequal living conditions, +and more. +

+ The ownership of facts is antithetical to many kinds of human progress. It’s +hard to imagine a rule that limits Big Tech’s exploitation of our collective +labors without inadvertently banning people from gathering data on online +harassment or compiling indexes of changes in language or simply +investigating how the platforms are shaping our discourse — all of which +require scraping data that other people have created and subjecting it to +scrutiny and analysis. +

Persuasion works… slowly

+ The platforms may oversell their ability to persuade people, but obviously, +persuasion works sometimes. Whether it’s the private realm that LGBTQ people +used to recruit allies and normalize sexual diversity or the decadeslong +project to convince people that markets are the only efficient way to solve +complicated resource allocation problems, it’s clear that our societal +attitudes can change. +

+ The project of shifting societal attitudes is a game of inches and +years. For centuries, svengalis have purported to be able to accelerate this +process, but even the most brutal forms of propaganda have struggled to make +permanent changes. Joseph Goebbels was able to subject Germans to daily, +mandatory, hourslong radio broadcasts, to round up and torture and murder +dissidents, and to seize full control over their children’s education while +banning any literature, broadcasts, or films that did not comport with his +worldview. +

+ Yet, after 12 years of terror, once the war ended, Nazi ideology was largely +discredited in both East and West Germany, and a program of national truth +and reconciliation was put in its place. Racism and authoritarianism were +never fully abolished in Germany, but neither were the majority of Germans +irrevocably convinced of Nazism — and the rise of racist authoritarianism in +Germany today tells us that the liberal attitudes that replaced Nazism were +no more permanent than Nazism itself. +

+ Racism and authoritarianism have also always been with us. Anyone who’s +reviewed the kind of messages and arguments that racists put forward today +would be hard-pressed to say that they have gotten better at presenting +their ideas. The same pseudoscience, appeals to fear, and circular logic +that racists presented in the 1980s, when the cause of white supremacy was +on the wane, are to be found in the communications of leading white +nationalists today. +

+ If racists haven’t gotten more convincing in the past decade, then how is it +that more people were convinced to be openly racist at that time? I believe +that the answer lies in the material world, not the world of ideas. The +ideas haven’t gotten more convincing, but people have become more +afraid. Afraid that the state can’t be trusted to act as an honest broker in +life-or-death decisions, from those regarding the management of the economy +to the regulation of painkillers to the rules for handling private +information. Afraid that the world has become a game of musical chairs in +which the chairs are being taken away at a never-before-seen rate. Afraid +that justice for others will come at their expense. Monopolism isn’t the +cause of these fears, but the inequality and material desperation and policy +malpractice that monopolism contributes to is a significant contributor to +these conditions. Inequality creates the conditions for both conspiracies +and violent racist ideologies, and then surveillance capitalism lets +opportunists target the fearful and the conspiracy-minded. +

Paying won’t help

+ As the old saw goes, “If you’re not paying for the product, you’re the +product.” +

+ It’s a commonplace belief today that the advent of free, ad-supported media +was the original sin of surveillance capitalism. The reasoning is that the +companies that charged for access couldn’t “compete with free” +and so they were driven out of business. Their ad-supported competitors, +meanwhile, declared open season on their users’ data in a bid to improve +their ad targeting and make more money and then resorted to the most +sensationalist tactics to generate clicks on those ads. If only we’d pay for +media again, we’d have a better, more responsible, more sober discourse that +would be better for democracy. +

+ But the degradation of news products long precedes the advent of +ad-supported online news. Long before newspapers were online, lax antitrust +enforcement had opened the door for unprecedented waves of consolidation and +roll-ups in newsrooms. Rival newspapers were merged, reporters and ad sales +staff were laid off, physical plants were sold and leased back, leaving the +companies loaded up with debt through leveraged buyouts and subsequent +profit-taking by the new owners. In other words, it wasn’t merely shifts in +the classified advertising market, which was long held to be the primary +driver in the decline of the traditional newsroom, that made news companies +unable to adapt to the internet — it was monopolism. +

+ Then, as news companies did come online, the ad +revenues they commanded dropped even as the number of internet users (and +thus potential online readers) increased. That shift was a function of +consolidation in the ad sales market, with Google and Facebook emerging as +duopolists who made more money every year from advertising while paying less +and less of it to the publishers whose work the ads appeared +alongside. Monopolism created a buyer’s market for ad inventory with +Facebook and Google acting as gatekeepers. +

+ Paid services continue to exist alongside free ones, and often it is these +paid services — anxious to prevent people from bypassing their paywalls or +sharing paid media with freeloaders — that exert the most control over their +customers. Apple’s iTunes and App Stores are paid services, but to maximize +their profitability, Apple has to lock its platforms so that third parties +can’t make compatible software without permission. These locks allow the +company to exercise both editorial control (enabling it to exclude controversial +political material) and technological control, including control +over who can repair the devices it makes. If we’re worried that ad-supported +products deprive people of their right to self-determination by using +persuasion techniques to nudge their purchase decisions a few degrees in one +direction or the other, then the near-total control a single company holds +over the decision of who gets to sell you software, parts, and service for +your iPhone should have us very worried indeed. +

+ We shouldn’t just be concerned about payment and control: The idea that +paying will improve discourse is also dangerously wrong. The poor success +rate of targeted advertising means that the platforms have to incentivize +you to “engage” with posts at extremely high levels to generate +enough pageviews to safeguard their profits. As discussed earlier, to +increase engagement, platforms like Facebook use machine learning to guess +which messages will be most inflammatory and make a point of shoving those +into your eyeballs at every turn so that you will hate-click and argue with +people. +

+ Perhaps paying would fix this, the reasoning goes. If platforms could be +economically viable even if you stopped clicking on them once your +intellectual and social curiosity had been slaked, then they would have no +reason to algorithmically enrage you to get more clicks out of you, right? +

+ There may be something to that argument, but it still ignores the wider +economic and political context of the platforms and the world that allowed +them to grow so dominant. +

+ Platforms are world-spanning and all-encompassing because they are +monopolies, and they are monopolies because we have gutted our most +important and reliable anti-monopoly rules. Antitrust was neutered as a key +part of the project to make the wealthy wealthier, and that project has +worked. The vast majority of people on Earth have a negative net worth, and +even the dwindling middle class is in a precarious state, undersaved for +retirement, underinsured for medical disasters, and undersecured against +climate and technology shocks. +

+ In this wildly unequal world, paying doesn’t improve the discourse; it +simply prices discourse out of the range of the majority of people. Paying +for the product is dandy, if you can afford it. +

+ If you think today’s filter bubbles are a problem for our discourse, imagine +what they’d be like if rich people inhabited free-flowing Athenian +marketplaces of ideas where you have to pay for admission while everyone +else lives in online spaces that are subsidized by wealthy benefactors who +relish the chance to establish conversational spaces where the “house +rules” forbid questioning the status quo. That is, imagine if the +rich seceded from Facebook, and then, instead of running ads that made money +for shareholders, Facebook became a billionaire’s vanity project that also +happened to ensure that nobody talked about whether it was fair that only +billionaires could afford to hang out in the rarified corners of the +internet. +

+ Behind the idea of paying for access is a belief that free markets will +address Big Tech’s dysfunction. After all, to the extent that people have a +view of surveillance at all, it is generally an unfavorable one, and the +longer and more thoroughly one is surveilled, the less one tends to like +it. Same goes for lock-in: If HP’s ink or Apple’s App Store were really +obviously fantastic, they wouldn’t need technical measures to prevent users +from choosing a rival’s product. The only reason these technical +countermeasures exist is that the companies don’t believe their customers +would voluntarily submit to their terms, and they want +to deprive them of the choice to take their business elsewhere. +

+ Advocates for markets laud their ability to aggregate the diffused knowledge +of buyers and sellers across a whole society through demand signals, price +signals, and so on. The argument for surveillance capitalism being a +“rogue capitalism” is that machine-learning-driven persuasion +techniques distort decision-making by consumers, leading to incorrect +signals — consumers don’t buy what they prefer, they buy what they’re +tricked into preferring. It follows that the monopolistic practices of +lock-in, which do far more to constrain consumers’ free choices, are even +more of a “rogue capitalism.” +

+ The profitability of any business is constrained by the possibility that its +customers will take their business elsewhere. Both surveillance and lock-in +are anti-features that no customer wants. But monopolies can capture their +regulators, crush their competitors, insert themselves into their customers’ +lives, and corral people into “choosing” their services +regardless of whether they want them — it’s fine to be terrible when there +is no alternative. +

+ Ultimately, surveillance and lock-in are both simply business strategies +that monopolists can choose. Surveillance companies like Google are +perfectly capable of deploying lock-in technologies — just look at the +onerous Android licensing terms that require device-makers to bundle in +Google’s suite of applications. And lock-in companies like Apple are +perfectly capable of subjecting their users to surveillance if it means +keeping the Chinese government happy and preserving ongoing access to +Chinese markets. Monopolies may be made up of good, ethical people, but as +institutions, they are not your friend — they will do whatever they can get +away with to maximize their profits, and the more monopolistic they are, the +more they can get away with. +

An “ecology” moment for trustbusting

+ If we’re going to break Big Tech’s death grip on our digital lives, we’re +going to have to fight monopolies. That may sound pretty mundane and +old-fashioned, something out of the New Deal era, while ending the use of +automated behavioral modification feels like the plotline of a really cool +cyberpunk novel. +

+ Meanwhile, breaking up monopolies is something we seem to have forgotten how +to do. There is a bipartisan, trans-Atlantic consensus that breaking up +companies is a fool’s errand at best — liable to mire your federal +prosecutors in decades of litigation — and counterproductive at worst, +eroding the “consumer benefits” of large companies with massive +efficiencies of scale. +

+ But trustbusters once strode the nation, brandishing law books, terrorizing +robber barons, and shattering the illusion of monopolies’ all-powerful grip +on our society. The trustbusting era could not begin until we found the +political will — until the people convinced politicians they’d have their +backs when they went up against the richest, most powerful men in the world. +

+ Could we find that political will again? +

+ Copyright scholar James Boyle has described how the term +“ecology” marked a turning point in environmental +activism. Prior to the adoption of this term, people who wanted to preserve +whale populations didn’t necessarily see themselves as fighting the same +battle as people who wanted to protect the ozone layer or fight freshwater +pollution or beat back smog or acid rain. +

+ But the term “ecology” welded these disparate causes together +into a single movement, and the members of this movement found solidarity +with one another. The people who cared about smog signed petitions +circulated by the people who wanted to end whaling, and the anti-whalers +marched alongside the people demanding action on acid rain. This uniting +behind a common cause completely changed the dynamics of environmentalism, +setting the stage for today’s climate activism and the sense that preserving +the habitability of the planet Earth is a shared duty among all people. +

+ I believe we are on the verge of a new “ecology” moment +dedicated to combating monopolies. After all, tech isn’t the only +concentrated industry nor is it even the most +concentrated of industries. +

+ You can find partisans for trustbusting in every sector of the +economy. Everywhere you look, you can find people who’ve been wronged by +monopolists who’ve trashed their finances, their health, their privacy, +their educations, and the lives of people they love. Those people have the +same cause as the people who want to break up Big Tech and the same +enemies. When most of the world’s wealth is in the hands of a very few, it +follows that nearly every large company will have overlapping shareholders. +

+ That’s the good news: With a little bit of work and a little bit of +coalition building, we have more than enough political will to break up Big +Tech and every other concentrated industry besides. First we take Facebook, +then we take AT&T/WarnerMedia. +

+ But here’s the bad news: Much of what we’re doing to tame Big Tech +instead of breaking up the big companies also +forecloses on the possibility of breaking them up later. +

+ Big Tech’s concentration currently means that their inaction on harassment, +for example, leaves users with an impossible choice: absent themselves from +public discourse by, say, quitting Twitter or endure vile, constant +abuse. Big Tech’s over-collection and over-retention of data results in +horrific identity theft. And their inaction on extremist recruitment means +that white supremacists who livestream their shooting rampages can reach an +audience of billions. The combination of tech concentration and media +concentration means that artists’ incomes are falling even as the revenue +generated by their creations are increasing. +

+ Yet governments confronting all of these problems all inevitably converge on +the same solution: deputize the Big Tech giants to police their users and +render them liable for their users’ bad actions. The drive to force Big Tech +to use automated filters to block everything from copyright infringement to +sex-trafficking to violent extremism means that tech companies will have to +allocate hundreds of millions to run these compliance systems. +

+ These rules — the EU’s new Directive on Copyright, Australia’s new terror +regulation, America’s FOSTA/SESTA sex-trafficking law and more — are not +just death warrants for small, upstart competitors that might challenge Big +Tech’s dominance but who lack the deep pockets of established incumbents to +pay for all these automated systems. Worse still, these rules put a floor +under how small we can hope to make Big Tech. +

+ That’s because any move to break up Big Tech and cut it down to size will +have to cope with the hard limit of not making these companies so small that +they can no longer afford to perform these duties — and it’s +expensive to invest in those automated filters and +outsource content moderation. It’s already going to be hard to unwind these +deeply concentrated, chimeric behemoths that have been welded together in +the pursuit of monopoly profits. Doing so while simultaneously finding some +way to fill the regulatory void that will be left behind if these +self-policing rulers were forced to suddenly abdicate will be much, much +harder. +

+ Allowing the platforms to grow to their present size has given them a +dominance that is nearly insurmountable — deputizing them with public duties +to redress the pathologies created by their size makes it virtually +impossible to reduce that size. Lather, rinse, repeat: If the platforms +don’t get smaller, they will get larger, and as they get larger, they will +create more problems, which will give rise to more public duties for the +companies, which will make them bigger still. +

+ We can work to fix the internet by breaking up Big Tech and depriving them +of monopoly profits, or we can work to fix Big Tech by making them spend +their monopoly profits on governance. But we can’t do both. We have to +choose between a vibrant, open internet or a dominated, monopolized internet +commanded by Big Tech giants that we struggle with constantly to get them to +behave themselves. +

Make Big Tech small again

+ Trustbusting is hard. Breaking big companies into smaller ones is expensive +and time-consuming. So time-consuming that by the time you’re done, the +world has often moved on and rendered years of litigation irrelevant. From +1969 to 1982, the U.S. government pursued an antitrust case against IBM over +its dominance of mainframe computing — but the case collapsed in 1982 +because mainframes were being speedily replaced by PCs. +

+ A future U.S. president could simply direct their attorney general to +enforce the law as it was written. +

+ It’s far easier to prevent concentration than to fix it, and reinstating the +traditional contours of U.S. antitrust enforcement will, at the very least, +prevent further concentration. That means bans on mergers between large +companies, on big companies acquiring nascent competitors, and on platform +companies competing directly with the companies that rely on the platforms. +

+ These powers are all in the plain language of U.S. antitrust laws, so in +theory, a future U.S. president could simply direct their attorney general +to enforce the law as it was written. But after decades of judicial +“education” in the benefits of monopolies, after multiple +administrations that have packed the federal courts with lifetime-appointed +monopoly cheerleaders, it’s not clear that mere administrative action would +do the trick. +

+ If the courts frustrate the Justice Department and the president, the next +stop would be Congress, which could eliminate any doubt about how antitrust +law should be enforced in the U.S. by passing new laws that boil down to +saying, “Knock it off. We all know what the Sherman Act says. Robert +Bork was a deranged fantasist. For avoidance of doubt, fuck that +guy.” In other words, the problem with monopolies is +monopolism — the concentration of power into too few +hands, which erodes our right to self-determination. If there is a monopoly, +the law wants it gone, period. Sure, get rid of monopolies that create +“consumer harm” in the form of higher prices, but also, +get rid of other monopolies, too. +

+ But this only prevents things from getting worse. To help them get better, +we will have to build coalitions with other activists in the anti-monopoly +ecology movement — a pluralism movement or a self-determination movement — +and target existing monopolies in every industry for breakup and structural +separation rules that prevent, for example, the giant eyewear monopolist +Luxottica from dominating both the sale and the manufacture of spectacles. +

+ In an important sense, it doesn’t matter which industry the breakups begin +in. Once they start, shareholders in every industry +will start to eye their investments in monopolists skeptically. As +trustbusters ride into town and start making lives miserable for +monopolists, the debate around every corporate boardroom’s table will +shift. People within corporations who’ve always felt uneasy about monopolism +will gain a powerful new argument to fend off their evil rivals in the +corporate hierarchy: “If we do it my way, we make less money; if we do +it your way, a judge will fine us billions and expose us to ridicule and +public disapprobation. So even though I get that it would be really cool to +do that merger, lock out that competitor, or buy that little company and +kill it before it can threaten it, we really shouldn’t — not if we don’t +want to get tied to the DOJ’s bumper and get dragged up and down Trustbuster +Road for the next 10 years.” +

20 GOTO 10

+ Fixing Big Tech will require a lot of iteration. As cyber lawyer Lawrence +Lessig wrote in his 1999 book, Code and Other Laws of +Cyberspace, our lives are regulated by four forces: law (what’s +legal), code (what’s technologically possible), norms (what’s socially +acceptable), and markets (what’s profitable). +

+ If you could wave a wand and get Congress to pass a law that re-fanged the +Sherman Act tomorrow, you could use the impending breakups to convince +venture capitalists to fund competitors to Facebook, Google, Twitter, and +Apple that would be waiting in the wings after they were cut down to size. +

+ But getting Congress to act will require a massive normative shift, a mass +movement of people who care about monopolies — and pulling them apart. +

+ Getting people to care about monopolies will take technological +interventions that help them to see what a world free from Big Tech might +look like. Imagine if someone could make a beloved (but unauthorized) +third-party Facebook or Twitter client that dampens the anxiety-producing +algorithmic drumbeat and still lets you talk to your friends without being +spied upon — something that made social media more sociable and less +toxic. Now imagine that it gets shut down in a brutal legal battle. It’s +always easier to convince people that something must be done to save a thing +they love than it is to excite them about something that doesn’t even exist +yet. +

+ Neither tech nor law nor code nor markets are sufficient to reform Big +Tech. But a profitable competitor to Big Tech could bankroll a legislative +push; legal reform can embolden a toolsmith to make a better tool; the tool +can create customers for a potential business who value the benefits of the +internet but want them delivered without Big Tech; and that business can get +funded and divert some of its profits to legal reform. 20 GOTO 10 (or +lather, rinse, repeat). Do it again, but this time, get farther! After all, +this time you’re starting with weaker Big Tech adversaries, a constituency +that understands things can be better, Big Tech rivals who’ll help ensure +their own future by bankrolling reform, and code that other programmers can +build on to weaken Big Tech even further. +

+ The surveillance capitalism hypothesis — that Big Tech’s products really +work as well as they say they do and that’s why everything is so screwed up +— is way too easy on surveillance and even easier on capitalism. Companies +spy because they believe their own BS, and companies spy because governments +let them, and companies spy because any advantage from spying is so +short-lived and minor that they have to do more and more of it just to stay +in place. +

+ As to why things are so screwed up? Capitalism. Specifically, the monopolism +that creates inequality and the inequality that creates monopolism. It’s a +form of capitalism that rewards sociopaths who destroy the real economy to +inflate the bottom line, and they get away with it for the same reason +companies get away with spying: because our governments are in thrall to +both the ideology that says monopolies are actually just fine and in thrall +to the ideology that says that in a monopolistic world, you’d better not +piss off the monopolists. +

+ Surveillance doesn’t make capitalism rogue. Capitalism’s unchecked rule +begets surveillance. Surveillance isn’t bad because it lets people +manipulate us. It’s bad because it crushes our ability to be our authentic +selves — and because it lets the rich and powerful figure out who might be +thinking of building guillotines and what dirt they can use to discredit +those embryonic guillotine-builders before they can even get to the +lumberyard. +

Up and through

+ With all the problems of Big Tech, it’s tempting to imagine solving the +problem by returning to a world without tech at all. Resist that temptation. +

+ The only way out of our Big Tech problem is up and through. If our future is +not reliant upon high tech, it will be because civilization has fallen. Big +Tech wired together a planetary, species-wide nervous system that, with the +proper reforms and course corrections, is capable of seeing us through the +existential challenge of our species and planet. Now it’s up to us to seize +the means of computation, putting that electronic nervous system under +democratic, accountable control. +

+ I am, secretly, despite what I have said earlier, a tech exceptionalist. Not +in the sense of thinking that tech should be given a free pass to monopolize +because it has “economies of scale” or some other nebulous +feature. I’m a tech exceptionalist because I believe that getting tech right +matters and that getting it wrong will be an unmitigated catastrophe — and +doing it right can give us the power to work together to save our +civilization, our species, and our planet. +

diff --git a/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.pdf b/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.pdf new file mode 100644 index 0000000..0daa3e9 Binary files /dev/null and b/public/how-to-destroy-surveillance-capitalism.fr.pdf differ diff --git a/public/index.html b/public/index.html index b380670..4cabb28 100644 --- a/public/index.html +++ b/public/index.html @@ -20,6 +20,13 @@
  • ePub
  • +

    French edition draft is being worked on:

    + +

    Polish edition draft is being worked on: